Hedging in Islamic Finance by Bashir Ali Khallat

From HodHood
Jump to: navigation, search

HEDGING

IN ISLAMIC FINANCE

  SAMI AL-SUWAILEM
  Occasional Paper No. 10
 Rab�c II, 1427 H – May, 2006 G


� Islamic Development Bank, 2006

    King Fahad National Library Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Al-Suwailem, Sami

    Hedging in Islamic Finance/Sami Al-Suwailem

Jeddah, 2006

    150 p; 24 � 17 cm
    ISBN: 9960-32-160-6
    1. Hedging (Finance)       2. Islamic finance

I. Title

    332.645 dc                 1427/1811
    L.D. no. 1427/1811
    ISBN: 9960-32-160-6



                                                      CONTENTS

Forward ix

Abstract xi

I. Introduction 13

   Risk Dilemma ........................................................................................................... 14
   Message of Islamic Finance ........................................................................................ 15
   Objective of the Paper ................................................................................................. 15
   Organization of the Paper ........................................................................................... 16
   Note on References ..................................................................................................... 17
   Acknowledgement ....................................................................................................... 17

II. State of Risk: Volatilities of Financial Markets 19

   Stock Markets ........................................................................................................... 19
   Commodities Markets................................................................................................. 22
   Currencies Markets .................................................................................................... 24
   Stability of Financial Markets..................................................................................... 25

III. Derivatives 27

   Structure of Derivatives ............................................................................................... 27
   Size of Derivatives Market ........................................................................................... 28
   Futures ..................................................................................................................... 30
   Options..................................................................................................................... 31
   Struggle for Legitimacy ............................................................................................... 32
   Economic Debate ....................................................................................................... 35
   Derivatives and Risk .................................................................................................. 36
   Willingness vs. Ability to Take Risks........................................................................... 37
   Commoditizing Risk .................................................................................................. 39
   Artificial Risks .......................................................................................................... 40
   Severance of Risk ....................................................................................................... 41
                                                                 v


  Risk and Time .......................................................................................................... 42
  Market Distribution................................................................................................... 42
  Law of Large Numbers............................................................................................... 44
  Systemic Risk ............................................................................................................ 45
  The Two Edges of Derivatives .................................................................................... 47
  Limits to Derivatives’ Protection .................................................................................. 48
  Who Ultimatley Bears the Risk? ................................................................................. 50
  Winner and Losers in Derivatives ................................................................................ 51
  Risk Dilemma........................................................................................................... 52

IV. The Islamic Approach 55

  Risk in Islamic Economics.......................................................................................... 56
  Hedging.................................................................................................................... 57
  Tolerable Risk .......................................................................................................... 58
  Inevitability of Risk ................................................................................................... 58
  Causality.................................................................................................................. 60
  Investment vs. Gambling............................................................................................. 61
  Choice under Uncertainty............................................................................................ 62
  A Causal Decision Rule ............................................................................................. 63
  Statistical Measure .................................................................................................... 65
  Derivatives ................................................................................................................ 67

V. Theory of Gharar 69

  Types of Games......................................................................................................... 69
  Measure of Gharar .................................................................................................... 73
  Characteristics of Zero-sum Games .............................................................................. 74
  Expected vs. Actual Measures ..................................................................................... 77
  Risk and Zero-sum Structure ...................................................................................... 79
  Two Measures of Gharar ........................................................................................... 82
  Value of Risk Management......................................................................................... 84

VI. Financial Engineering: An Islamic Perspective 87

  Definition and Concept............................................................................................... 87
  Value of Innovation.................................................................................................... 88
  Sharıcah and Creativity .............................................................................................. 89
                                                               vi


 Regulatory Arbitrage .................................................................................................. 90
 State of Financial Innovation ...................................................................................... 91
 Principles of Islamic Financial Engineering .................................................................. 92
 Principle of Balance ................................................................................................... 92
 Interdependence.......................................................................................................... 93
 Principle of Acceptability ............................................................................................ 95
 Roots of Prohibited Dealings ....................................................................................... 96
 Principle of Integration ............................................................................................... 98
 Integration and Specialization ..................................................................................... 99
 Evaluation of Financial Products............................................................................... 100
 Principle of Consistency ............................................................................................ 102
 Strategies of Product Development .............................................................................. 104
 Imitation................................................................................................................. 105
 Mutation ................................................................................................................ 107
 Satisfaction ............................................................................................................. 108
 Conclusion .............................................................................................................. 109

VII. Islamic Instruments for Hedging 111

 Economic Hedging ................................................................................................... 112
 Alignment of Assets and Liabilities............................................................................. 112
 Natural Hedge......................................................................................................... 114
 Dynamic Hedging .................................................................................................... 115
 Cooperative Hedging................................................................................................. 116
 Cooperative Hedging for Currency Risks ..................................................................... 118
 Bilateral Mutual Adjustment .................................................................................... 119
 Contractual Hedging ................................................................................................ 120
  Mudarabah .......................................................................................................... 121
 Misreporting Risk .................................................................................................... 121
 Credit-based Mudarabah ........................................................................................ 122
 Capital Risk ........................................................................................................... 123
 Third Party Hedging................................................................................................ 124
 Deferred-price Sale ................................................................................................... 125
 Liquidity Risk ......................................................................................................... 126
                                                             vii


 Rate of Return Risk ................................................................................................. 126
 Diversified Deferred Price ......................................................................................... 127
 Commodity-linked Bonds.......................................................................................... 129
 Currency Risk in Murabaha ................................................................................... 130
 Value-based Salam .................................................................................................. 131
 Discussion .............................................................................................................. 132
 Liquidity of Salam................................................................................................... 135
 Rate of Return Risk ................................................................................................. 136
 Other Applications of Value-based Salam................................................................... 136
 Payoff Structure of Contractual Hedging..................................................................... 137
 Specialized Institutions for Risk Management ............................................................. 138
 Summary ................................................................................................................ 139

VIII. Conclusion 141

References 143

                                                            viii


                               FORWARD

Development of Islamic financial products through appropriate

processes of financial engineering has remained an important area of

research at the Islamic Research and Training Institute since its

inception in 1981. Financial product development is also a priority

area for the Institute’s current and future research.

In this area the Islamic financial industry is facing two competing

challenges. Understandably, treasury managers of the Islamic financial

institutions face the immediate challenge of managing the financial

risks arising from their operations. In order to remain sustainable,

these institutions immediately need financial products that can be

utilized for hedging against the various financial risks. On the other

hand, the industry also needs such financial products that can

guarantee the industry’s long run viability as a genuinely distinct

business model. While the first is an immediate concern of treasury

management, the second is also of tremendous importance for the

future development of the industry.

                                    ix


The present Occasional Paper on “Hedging in Islamic Finance” by

Dr. Sami Al-Suwailem makes an attempt to systematically address the

second and more fundamental challenge. This approach is hoped not

only to address the future and more vital developmental challenges of

the industry, but it is also expected to put the immediate challenges of

the institutions in their proper perspective. The research puts the

economic analysis of the subject in perspective of the extensive

historical literature on Islamic finance and offers premises for

developing a number of Islamic financial products for hedging and risk

management.

Financial engineering helps in unpacking and decomposition of

financial risks that underlie assets in terms of their unique

characteristics. Hence financial engineering helps in the development

of financial products that can be used to hedge against those specific

risks. It is hoped that the present research will promote understanding

of the vital subject from the perspective of Islamic finance and

motivate other researchers to deal more intensively and in an objective

manner with the several ideas presented in the paper. The Institute

invites with encouragement such research works from interested

scholars.

Bashir Ali Khallat

Acting Director, IRTI

                                    x


                              ABSTRACT

The paper suggests several instruments for controlling and reducing

risks commonly associated with Islamic contracts. These include risks

of capital, rate of return, liquidity, as well as currency risks. Some

conventional hedging tools that appear consistent with Islamic

principles are also presented.

       In the process, the Islamic approach towards risk is surveyed,

and strategies for Islamic product development are outlined. Generally

speaking, from an Islamic point of view, risk cannot be traded

independent from ownership of the underlying asset. Prevailing

conventional instruments, in contrast, take the opposite direction. Risk

is severed from ownership and thus treated as a commodity in itself.

This makes risk management and wealth creation move in different

directions, and thus compete for scarce resources. More important,

commoditizing risk removes barriers on growth and proliferation of

risk, and its distribution becomes distorted against the more willing but

less able to bear it.

       Islamic hedging instruments         avoid these    ailments    by

integrating risk with ownership and thus value-adding activities. This

assures the possibility of mutual gain meanwhile reducing and

                                   xi


managing risks. Islamic instruments therefore combine risk

management with wealth creation, leading to better performance on

both fronts.

       Hedging could be also carried out through not-for-profit

arrangements. Mutual hedging serves the needs of involved parties in

avoiding risks with minimum restrictions. Since it is not for profit,

mutual hedging avoids the problems of speculation and increasing

systemic risks.

                                xii


                                    I
                            INTRODUCTION

Islamic financial industry is growing rapidly. Markets are increasingly

appreciating Islamic instruments, and more institutions are willing to

provide Islamic services to their clients. Yet, Islamic instruments,

particularly in the area of hedging and risk management, are not at

pace with the industry’s growth.

       Islamic financial institutions face a variety of types of risks

associated with Islamic modes of investment and finance. The need to

address these risks from an Islamic perspective is widely acknowledged

in the industry, and has been the subject of several studies, papers, as

well as conferences and workshops (e.g. Khan and Ahmed, 2001;

IFSB, 2005).

       This paper focuses on Islamic instruments for hedging risks

associated with Islamic finance. Although not all types of risk are

peculiar to Islamic modes, strategies to neutralize and manage such

risks are certainly different from conventional approaches.

       For this purpose the paper develops a general framework for

studying contracting under uncertainty, or gharar. This framework

then is used as a benchmark against which suggested instruments are

evaluated. Along the way, conventional instruments, mainly


14 I. INTRODUCTION

derivatives, are discussed. The contrast between the two types of

instruments accordingly becomes conceptually clear.

Risk Dilemma

       Risk is a challenge in both Islamic as well as conventional

finance. On one hand experts and specialists agree that no economic

growth can take place without taking risks. “Nothing ventured nothing

gained” is the first principle of investment. Further, total absence of

risk distorts incentives and hence deteriorates economic efficiency.

Thus, risk is inevitable for economic progress. On the other hand,

excessive risk will hurdle investment and deter growth. The question

then becomes: How to reach a balance between these two ends?

       Islamic finance provides a general approach for reaching the

answer to this crucial question. When it comes to for-profit

transactions, risk cannot be separated from ownership of real goods

and services. This is not because risk as such is desirable; in fact, it is

exactly the opposite. An effective strategy to minimize and control risk

is to have it integrated and embedded in real activities. In this manner,

risk becomes naturally controlled by real economy. Meanwhile this

would stimulate real activities to generate sufficient wealth in order to

compensate for such risks. Since these activities are the driving force

for economic growth, the strategy therefore helps achieve two goals at

once: creating value and minimizing risk.

       Conventional finance provides many tools for managing risk.

Some of these are consistent with the Islamic approach, as discussed

later in the paper. However, prevailing instruments, namely


I. INTRODUCTION 15

derivatives, take the opposite direction: They separate risk from

underlying assets. This makes risk management and wealth creation

move in different directions, and thus compete for available limited

resources. Further, commoditization of risk leads to its proliferation

and disproportionate distribution. The final result is higher risks,

increasing instability and concentration of wealth. Unfortunately, with

exponential growth of derivatives, data show increasing market

volatilities, not increasing stability. As discussed later, experts are

increasingly aware of these instabilities and the associated costs to real

economies.

Message of Islamic Finance

        Islamic finance is not only for Muslims. It is for entire

humanity: “We have send you solely for the mercy of all worlds”

(21:107). This imposes a serious challenge to Muslim economists,

namely to successfully deliver the message of Allah (s.w.t) to humanity,

and positively contribute to world economic stability and prosperity.

Objective of the Paper

        The paper’s objective is to develop a framework for studying

risk and strategies for designing risk management instruments based

on Islamic principles and rules of exchange. Several instruments and

products are provided as applications to such strategies.


16 I. INTRODUCTION

Organization of the Paper

        The paper is organized as follows:
        Section II reviews volatilities of major financial markets. Data

show that volatilities are generally rising. This view is confirmed by

leading experts, researchers, as well as policy makers. Despite

ingenious risk management tools invented in the last decade, risks

appear increasing rather than decreasing.

        Section III reviews the ongoing debate on derivatives.

Derivatives as such can be used for both risk management as well as

pure speculation. The literature shows that derivatives presented a

difficult challenge to economists as well as legislators. The legal and

economic differences between speculation using derivatives and

wagering were and still not resolved. Economic consequences of rising

speculation are frequently associated with rising instability.

        Section IV presents an Islamic perspective on risk. The section

reviews positions of Muslim scholars regarding risk, and that risk as

such is not desirable for its own sake; rather, value-creation through

real activities is the objective. However, such activities inevitably

involve risk. How to distinguish legitimate risk taking from gambling is

discussed, and it is shown that the statistical median rule is an effective

measure in differentiating the two.

        Section V outlines a theory of gharar, based on Shar�cah rules as

well as economic reasoning. It is argued that gharar is a predominantly

zero-sum game, and that this structure distorts incentives and system

behavior causing higher risk and instability. The theory is integrated

with the Islamic perspective on risk to formulate a general framework


I. INTRODUCTION 17

of the subject. This framework is used as a basis for developing Islamic

instruments.

       Section VI discusses financial engineering from an Islamic

standpoint. Principles and strategies for product development are

presented and discussed, together with examples from contemporary

Islamic financial practices.

       Section    VII   suggests   three   hedging     strategies, each

encompassing several instruments. Each instrument is discussed and

evaluated. These instruments however are suggestive and are

presented to stimulate discussions on the subject rather than as

conclusively accepted contracts from Shar�cah standpoint.

       The conclusion is given in section VIII.

Note on References

       English references are cited by name and year, while Arabic

references are cited by name and number in brackets, e.g. al-Dharir

[12], without stating the year. Many references are available on the

Internet and thus quotations from such sources are not referenced to

page numbers. The web address however is cited in the References

section. When the source is simply a web site, the address as well as

the date it was visited is given in parentheses, e.g. (investopedia.com;

12.2005).

Acknowledgement

       Many ideas presented in the paper have been under

development for years. The paper builds on previous research, and


18 I. INTRODUCTION

benefited greatly from numerous discussions with colleagues as well as

practitioners in Islamic and conventional banks. I find it difficult to

recall all their names, but I shall not forget their positive contributions.

         My colleagues at IRTI provided numerous suggestions and

improvements. In particular, I’d like to thank Dr. Tariqullah Khan,

Dr. Habib Ahmed, and Dr. Salman Ali for encouragement and

helpful comments. I also thank Dr. Muhammed Tariq, director of the

treasury, and Dr. Muddasir Siddiqi, advisor to the legal department,

both from IDB Group, for their careful reading and critical comments.

Br. Ibrahim Gharbi from IDB Library provided immeasurable

support; I greatly appreciate his efforts.

         I consider the paper as a work-in-progress. The subject is vastly

rich and diverse, and it is beyond the capability of an individual

researcher to settle its fundamental complexities. The best the paper

hopes for is to point to proper directions for pursuing the subject, and

stimulate future research to find answers for the challenging questions.

If so, it would be a great achievement and a precious favor from Allah

(s.w.t.). Otherwise, I hope I don’t fail to get a single reward in case the

two were missed.


                                  II
                           STATE OF RISK:
              VOLATILITIES OF FINANCIAL MARKETS

The past decade witnessed significant financial crises in several parts of

the world, including South East Asia, Russia and Latin America, as

well as derivatives turmoil of LTCM, financial scandals of Enron,

Worldcom, Parmalat, and more recently, Refco.

       The detailed documentation of these events would span

hundreds of pages (see for example Partnoy, 2003, and Banks, 2004).

But there is an apparently general trend of increasing volatility in

financial markets that breeds and supports these crises, e.g. Tumpel-

Gugerell (2003). In this section we will have a quick look at volatility of

selected financial markets to examine this phenomenon.

Stock Markets

       While stock markets are generally volatile by nature, over time

stock markets are becoming more and more unstable. Figure 1 shows

data on the Dow Jones Industrial Average.

       There is more than one way to measure volatility. One

common measure is the standard deviation. Another measure is

number of days for which the gap between high and low values of the


20 II. STATE OF RISK

        Figure 1: Volatility of the Dow Jones Industrial Average
                             Source: djindexes.com

index exceeds a certain threshold (e.g. Sornette, 2003). The latter

measure is adopted here. To calculate volatility, let

            (hight �lowt )
       ut =                ,
                close t

be the gap between high and low values relative to the close value of

the index. Let u be the mean of the gap for the sample period. Define

            �1 if u > u
       dt = �
                       t
            �0 otherwise,

and let Vn = � t=1 dt .

                n
       Then Vn represents number of days for which the gap exceeds

the sample mean. We use a moving version of V, where n equals 252

(number of trading days in the year). This is presented in Figure 1.


II. STATE OF RISK 21

                      Figure 2: Volatility of S&P 500
                          Source: finance.yahoo.com

The sample period for the DJ index is January 1, 1990 to December 9,

2005. For the sample period, mean gap u is 2.2%.

        As it is apparent from the graph in Figure 1, late nineties and

early this century witnessed an increasing volatility as compared to

early nineties. Average number of volatile days in 2000-2004 is 159

days. In comparison, the average for the period 1990-1994 is 38.6

days. That is, number of volatile days had quadrupled during this

period. Volatility however declined during 2005, but we are not

certain whether this is a trend or a temporary change.

        Figure 2 shows data for the S&P 500 index. Again, the

increasing volatility is obvious. Average number of days with high

volatility during 1990-1994 is 52. For the period 2000-2004 it is about


22 II. STATE OF RISK

                    Figure 3: Volatility of FTSE 100
                        Source: finance.yahoo.com

156 days. Volatility declined for 2005, as in the Dow Jones index,

which may or may not be a change in trend.

       Figure 3 shows the volatility of FTSE100 index of the largest

100 UK companies listed on London stock exchange. The pattern is

close to that of the Dow Jones and S&P 500 indices. Average number

of volatile days during 1990-1994 is 53.9, while that for 2000-2004 is

159 days. Volatility also declined for 2005. Future data would help

determine the range of this reduction.

Commodities Markets

       If we move to commodities markets, we a find a similar

pattern. Figure 4 shows volatility in Dow Jones Commodities Index

(DG-AIGCI). The index represents rolling futures on 19 commodities.


II. STATE OF RISK 23

              Figure 4: Volatility of DJ Commodities Index
                            Source: djindexes.com

These include: Energy commodities (33%), grains (18.4%), vegetable

oil (2.7%), livestock (10.5%), precious metals (8%), industrial metals

(18.2%), softs (9.2%).

       Figure 4 shows number of days for which absolute change in

daily price compared to the previous day exceeds average change of

the sample (0.57%). The number represents the sum of days for the

past year (252 days). The increase in volatility over the past 15 years is

substantial. This might be affected by the Iraq war and its impact on

oil prices. But the rise in volatility started much earlier than that, as

the graph shows.

       Average volatile days per year in the period 1991-1994 are 57

days. For the period 2001-2004 it is 123.


24 II. STATE OF RISK

                   Figure 5: Volatility of USD Index
                            Source: nybot.com

Currencies Markets

       Figure 5 shows volatility in the exchange rate of a basket of

currencies against the US Dollar, based on the index developed by

New York Board of Trade (USDX, nybot.com). The index is

composed of Euro (57.6%), Yen (13.6%), British Pound (11.9%),

Canadian Dollar (9.1%), Sweden Krona (4.2%), and Swiss Franc

(3.6%).

       The figure shows number of days for which High-Low

difference of the USDX as a percentage of Close exceeds the average

difference of the period (about 0.73%). The sum runs through 365

days per year, as the currency market is open around the clock.

       Overall, the USDX appears somehow more volatile from 1997

and on than before. Average number of volatile days per year in 1990-

1994 is 106.5, while that for the period 2000-2004 is 134, which is


II. STATE OF RISK 25

more than 26% increase in volatility. The medians for the two periods

are 100.5 and 138, respectively, which represents about 38%

difference.

         The following Table summarizes the above results.
                                        Table 1
                       Volatilities of Selected Markets
                                        1990-1994               2000-2004
                                      mean        median      mean     median

DJIA 38.6 27 159.4 199

S&P 500 52.1 36 156 176

FTSE 100 53.9 57 158.9 174

DJ Commodities index * 57 52 123 124

USD index 106.5 100.5 134.4 138

* Sample starts from 1991. Figures shown are for 1991-1994, 2001-2004,
respectively. Gap is measured by percentage change in price.

Stability of Financial Markets

         Table 1 shows a remarkable increase in volatilities in the past

decade. Markets volatilities increased by an average of 225%. Many

writers recognized this phenomenon. As early as 1996, Bernstein

pointed that “volatilities seems to be proliferating rather than

diminishing” (p. 329). The Asian crises and other episodes of the

nineties made Paul Krugman (1999) write: “The world economy has

turned out to be a much dangerous place than we imagined” (p. 154).

More recently, Gertrude Tumpel-Gugerell (2003), member of the


26 II. STATE OF RISK

Executive Board of the European Central Bank, argues that since

1997, volatility of leading stock markets has doubled, and that this

doubling was the result of a slow but steady rising trend. Nobel

laureate Joseph Stiglitz (2003, p. 54) concludes that: “Something is

wrong with the global financial system.”

        There are many factors that contributed to this increasing

volatility, and it would not be at all an easy task to pinpoint all these

factors. We shall focus instead on the most common tools used to

address volatility: derivatives.


                                 III
                            DERIVATIVES

Derivatives can be described as financial instruments for trading risk.

The most common of which includes futures, options, and swaps.

Theoretically, derivatives are supposed to distribute risk among

market participants in accordance with their ability to assume them. If

such distribution is achieved, each party would be better off, thus

improving efficiency and productivity. Derivatives are thus the main

instruments used conventionally to hedge various types of risk. But

they are also the main instruments for speculation. How to balance the

two functions is a major challenge to economists and legal scholars

alike.

        Given the two sides of derivatives, we will briefly discuss how

economists and specialists view the issue, leaving the Islamic

perspective to Section V.

Structure of Derivatives

        Derivatives are generally zero-sum exchanges between two

parties. According to former Federal Reserve Chairman, Alan

Greenspan (1999): “Overall, derivatives are mainly a zero-sum game:

one counterparty’s market loss is the other counterparty’s market


28 III. D ERIVATIVES

gain” (see also Group of Thirty, 1994, p. 64). Options and futures are

examples of zero-sum games, since for every party who gains the

counter-party loses (investopedia.com; 12.2005).

        As such, derivatives are not “real” transactions since no

transfer of ownership takes place. Only money changes hands at the

end of the contract. Delivery of underlying assets is very rare; in

futures, for example, 99% of all contracts are settled before maturity

(Pilbeam, 2005). For this reason, the Financial Services Authority of

the UK defines derivatives as “contract for differences” (Swan, 2000,

p. 11). That is, they are settled through price differences without

delivery or ownership transfer. We will see later how this feature

affects the risk structure of derivatives.

        It should be emphasized that contracts that transfer ownership

and explicitly involve delivery of the underlying are not considered

derivatives, and thus are excluded from subsequent discussions.

Further, spot trading of shares or other assets is not a zero-sum game

as such, since profits and losses are not debited from one party and

credited to the other, as it is the case in derivatives. Moreover, trading

implies the transfer of ownership, which does not take place in

derivatives. This is further explained in section V.

Size of Derivatives Market

        Derivatives can be traded generally in one of two markets:

Organized exchanges (OE), and over-the-counter (OTC). Organized

exchanges, like Chicago Board of Options Exchange (CBOE), are

regulated and centralized markets for standardized derivatives. Over-


III. D ERIVATIVES 29

the-counter are decentralized, less regulated markets for less

standardized derivatives.

       Data collected by the Bank of International Settlement shows

that derivatives have been growing at a remarkable rate. Figure 6

shows size of the two markets based on BIS data.

                 Figure 6: Notional Values of Derivatives
                               Source: bis.org

The notional amount represents the value of the underlying asset from

which the derivative is derived. Total notional amount of derivatives

today reaches $330 trillions, up from less than $100 trillions in 1998.

That is, derivatives more than tripled in less than 7 years. In 1986, OE

derivatives were about $614 billions. In two decades the derivatives

markets overall grew by a factor of more than 300. This exceeds the

growth rate of any type of securities or assets in world economy.


30 III. D ERIVATIVES

Futures

       “Futures” refer to standardized tradable forward contracts.

Forwards, in turn, represent an agreement to deliver a defined

commodity in a future date for a determined price. Forwards as such

are common to human economic activities, so they are not new.

Tradable forwards were known since the time of Imam M�lik (179H,

circa 800G) in Madinah, where salam (forwards) contracts where

allowed by the M�liki school to be traded in a secondary market (e.g.

al-Dharir [12]). However, forwards involving essential food

commodities (wheat, barely, dates and salt) were not allowed to be

traded in a secondary market, following the instruction of the Prophet

(peace be upon him) that food cannot be sold without being possessed

in advance. In other words, tradable forwards in principle were known

and established more than 1200 years ago.

       But these futures differ from contemporary futures in two

fundamental aspects: advanced payment and delivery. In all salam

contracts, the full price must be paid in advance. Further, the

underlying commodity must be delivered at maturity, and there are

several restrictions on subsequent canceling and settling of the contract

without delivery. These two sets of conditions prevented the contract

from being used for pure speculative purposes, whereby it ends up in

exchanging money for money, a result that Muslim scholars

unanimously consider to be void and null.

       Organized futures, where most contracts end up in settling

price differences, are relatively recent phenomenon. The first such


III. D ERIVATIVES 31

organized market was probably established in Japan in 1730 (Teweles

and Jones 1987, p. 8), where no delivery would take place.

        In 1848 the Chicago Board of Trade established the first

organized futures exchange in the West. In the beginning, however, it

was an exchange of forwards, i.e. commodities with future delivery.

Only in 1865 where futures started trading (see: cbot.com; 12.2005).

In 1877 futures trading became more formalized, and “speculators”

would be recognized as market players (ibid). Subsequently, the futures

market grew in size, and other exchanges introduced futures trading

(Teweles and Jones, 1987).

        Today, futures are traded for all kinds of assets: equities,

bonds, currencies, interest rates, indices, volatilities, etc.

Options

        In its basic form, the idea of a stipulated sale with penalty is

quite old. cUrbun was one such contract, where the buyer would pay a

down-payment with the condition that, if he cancels the contract, he

would lose his down-payment. It was known since the time of the

second Caliph cOmar ibn al-Khattab (22H, circa 700G) (al-Dharir

[12]). However, as such it was not used for speculation, i.e. fixing

current price to benefit from future price movements, but for real

trade transactions; i.e. they were “real options” (see al-Suwailem,

1999).

        Options were actively traded in Amsterdam in the seventeenth

century. In the U.S., options appeared in the same time as stocks, the

early nineteenth century (Sullivan, 2005). In addition to speculation,


32 III. D ERIVATIVES

put-call parity was used in mid 1800s to advance loans for much

higher interest rate than allowed by usury laws (Chance, 1995).

Option trading, however, remained limited until Black, Merton and

Scholes published their formula for pricing (stock) options in 1973. At

the same year, Chicago Board of Options Exchange was founded after

years of study and planning (cboe.com, 12.2005; Sullivan, 2005),

where call options started to be traded. Put options had to wait until

1977, with careful monitoring by SEC (Sullivan, 2005).

        Other forms of derivatives, e.g. swaps, short-selling, etc., have

their own histories, which go beyond the scope of this paper.

Struggle for Legitimacy

        Since its early appearance around the middle of the nineteenth

century, derivatives, mainly futures and options, were subject of

prolonged and intense discussions on whether they were legitimate

business and trading instruments or merely gambling tools. According

to legal scholar Roy Kreitner (2000), “at common law it was accepted

that transactions for future delivery of property, including stocks and

commodities, in which the parties did not intend actual delivery, but

rather only settlement according to price differences, were

unenforceable because they were mere wagers” (p. 1103). This made

courts in many instances not sympathetic to these contracts. In one

case in 1888, the court expresses it opinion as follows:

        We are clearly of opinion that dealing in “futures” or
        “options,” as they are commonly called, to be settled
        according to the fluctuations of the market, is void by the
        common law; for, among other reasons, it is contrary to


III. D ERIVATIVES 33

        public policy. It is … a crime – a crime against the state, a
        crime against the general welfare and happiness of the
        people, a crime against religion and morality, and a crime
        against all legitimate trade and business.
              This species of gambling has become emphatically
        and pre-eminently the national sin. … Clothed with
        respectability, and entrenched behind wealth and power,
        it submits to no restraint, and defies alike the laws of God
        and man. … Through its instrumentality the laws of
        supply and demand have been reversed, and the market is
        ruled by the amount of money its manipulators can bring
        to bear upon it. (Kreitner, 2000, p.1110.)

Although not all courts were of this position, as Kreitner points out,

the general trend in the first half of the nineteenth century was in this

direction (Swan, 2000, p. 219).

        A critical difference between a legitimate future contract and a

wager was delivery of the promised commodity. Courts frequently

used the “intent test” to decide whether the parties intended to deliver,

and thus the transaction was enforceable, or intended to settle in

differences, whereby the transaction was a wager (Kreitner, 2000;

Swan, 2000, pp. 212, 219).

        There were many attempts to have the Congress illegalize

futures and options, backed mainly by farmers and their supporters

(Freeman, 1993; Saber, 1999b, pp. 201-202; Swan, 2002, pp. 217,

245; Santos, 2004). In 1890, a Congressman expressed the opposition

to derivatives:

        Those who deal in “options” and “futures” contracts,
        which is merely gambling, no matter by what less offensive
        name such transactions be designated, neither add to the
        supply nor increase the demand for consumption, nor do
        they accomplish any useful purpose by their calling; but
        on the contrary, they speculate in fictitious products. The


34 III. D ERIVATIVES

        wheat they buy and sell is known as “wind wheat” and
        doubtless for the reason that it is invisible, intangible, and
        felt or realized only in the terrible force it exerts in
        destroying the farming industry of the country. (Teweles
        and Jones 1987, p. 11.)

More recently, in 1993 representative Henry Gonzalez, chairman of

House Banking Committee, described derivatives trading saying: “You

can call it whatever you want, but in my book it is gambling”

(Steinherr, 2000, p. 151).

        Several US states at some point in time did prohibit dealing in

options and futures. According to Santos (2004), the Illinois

constitution in 1867 forbade dealing in futures, but this was repealed

by 1869. In 1879 California’s constitution invalidated futures, but was

repealed in 1908. In early 1880s, Mississippi, Arkansas and Texas

passed laws that equated futures trading with gambling, thus making

futures trading a misdemeanor. Options on agricultural commodities

were outlawed on most exchanges (ibid), and were not officially

legalized until 1983 (Freeman, 1993). Despite repeated attempts to

illegalize futures, all failed except one: in 1958 the Congress passed a

bill to prohibit futures trading in onions (Teweles and Jones, 1987).

        It is worth noting that the legality of futures is related to

organized exchanges. According to Kreitner (2000), “Private

individuals cannot create enforceable contracts with one another for

futures, unless they actually intend delivery” (ftn. 28).

        This legal transition apparently affected the laws of some

Muslim countries early past century. The Egyptian law used to classify

futures as wagering until 1909, when the law made futures traded in


III. D ERIVATIVES 35

organized exchange as legal (al-Dharir [12]; pp. 619-620). The law

however confines this exception to organized exchanges, so that any

forward contract settled through price differences outside the

exchange is still considered void (ibid).

Economic Debate

        The debate wasn’t confined to legislative circles. Economists

and investors were also involved. Many economists believe that

markets, in principle, are efficient, and therefore whatever market

players agree to trade would serve their needs and consequently the

social good. This is the prevailing view, and expressed most notably by

economists like Merton Miller and others who generally accept the

efficient market hypothesis (see e.g. Financial Economists Roundtable,

1994).

        On the other hand, many mainstream economists and

investors express concerns about the behavior of financial markets in

general, which extends naturally to derivatives, as the most important

tools for speculation. Keynes (1936) was among early economists who

expressed dissatisfaction with gambling-like financial market:

        Speculators may do no harm as bubbles on a steady
        stream of enterprise. But the position is serious when
        enterprise becomes the bubble on a whirlpool of
        speculation. When the capital development of a country
        becomes the by-product of the activities of a casino, the
        job is likely to be ill-done (p. 159).

About 70 years later, Noble laureate M. Allais (1993) describes such

markets as “casinos where gigantic games of poker are played” (p. 35).


36 III. D ERIVATIVES

While acknowledges the value of forward arrangements for hedging,

particularly for real goods and commodities, Allais questions the value

of forwards on securities, like stocks and bonds (p. 37). Further, he

explicitly states, “speculation on security price indices must be

eliminated” (ibid).

        On the business front, Warren Buffet, one of the most

successful investors and Columbia University graduate, takes a strong

position against derivatives. In his letter to shareholders he describes

derivatives as “time bombs, both for the parties that deal in them and

the economic system” (p. 13). Further, Buffet argues that derivatives

can exacerbate the risks at the firm’s level and at market level, and

that the “macro picture is dangerous and getting more so” (p. 14). He

concludes the discussion stating that: “In our view, however,

derivatives are financial weapons of mass destruction, carrying dangers

that, while now latent, are potentially lethal” (Buffet, 2002, p. 15).

        General Electric, one of the largest corporations in the U.S., is

involved in financial business through its subsidiary, GE Capital

(GECS), which owns more assets than most U.S. banks. GE’s position

regarding derivatives is summarized in its 2001 annual report: “As a

matter of policy, neither GE nor GECS engages in derivatives trading,

derivatives market-making, or other speculative activities” (cited in

Partnoy, 2003, p. 380).

Derivatives and Risk

        Proponents of derivatives argue that these instruments can

efficiently distribute risks among involved parties, such that agents


III. D ERIVATIVES 37

become more productive and the economy more prosperous. The

classical example cited is of a producer (of agricultural commodities or

energy products) who is uncertain of future prices. He can hedge

against this uncertainty using futures, thus real production may not be

hindered by uncertainty. The counterparty to such contract would be

one who is more able to take price risks, and this is the speculator.

Thus, for every hedger, there is a speculator. This transfer of risk from

hedgers (real producers) to speculators is supposed to improve

efficiency and productivity of the economy. In other words, derivatives

manage risks but do not create them (Spence, 1997).

        Critics, however, point to aspects that this reasoning ignores:

Willingness vs. Ability to Take Risks

        One aspect is that risk can be traded and “unbundled” only if

it’s severed from the underlying activity. This separation raises the

question of the ability of traders to manage these risks. For example,

credit default swaps allow banks to transfer the risk of default of

borrowers to other parties like insurance companies. But banks by

design are better able to monitor borrowers and uniquely have the

access to necessary related data. Insurance companies are less able to

manage these loans and thus to assume these risks (Partnoy, 2003, pp.

380-381). This is reinforced by the mounting evidence of prevailing

informational asymmetries and other imperfections in capital markets.

These asymmetries make it costly to third parties to perform the same

functions as the owners of original assets, and thus performance and

pricing might be distorted significantly. Unbundling of risks therefore


38 III. D ERIVATIVES

is built on the assumption of perfect markets with full and symmetric

information, which modern information theory has shown to be

largely inconsistent with reality. In 2001, George Akerlof, Michael

Spence and Joseph Stiglitz were awarded Nobel prize for their work

on information economics. In his Nobel lecture, Stiglitz (2001)

explains how his direct experience conflicted with economic models he

was taught 40 years ago. His subsequent research, as well as that of

many prominent economists, has shown how information changes the

way agents behave, and thus significantly affects market equilibrium.

The assumption therefore that risk can be traded separately is simply

inconsistent with large evidence that this cannot produce efficient

results. Lenders are better able to monitor their borrowers, and thus to

minimize their risks. Once this specific relationship is severed, risks are

likely to develop rather than be controlled.

        Derivatives markets allow risk to be transferred to those more

willing to take them, but not necessarily those who are more able to

manage them. Greenspan (2002) implicitly points to the difference:

“The development of our paradigms for containing risk has

emphasized dispersion of risk to those willing, and presumably able, to

bear it” (emphasis added). This presumption, however, is not

necessarily warranted, as these two concepts are independent. There

are certainly many speculators who are more willing to take risks but

are less able to bear them. This is particularly the case for low net-

worth, cash-constrained agents who might be more willing to take risks

if they are paid upfront, even though they are less able to bear such

risks. They gain needed cash for certain, but have less to lose if they


III. D ERIVATIVES 39

fail. This is the classical adverse selection problem that arises in

relation to imperfections and asymmetric information. Consequently,

the system might end up allocating risks to those least able to bear them,

but are the most willing to take them. As will be pointed later, this in

fact might be the case.

Commoditizing Risk

        Derivatives unbundle risk from real economic activity and

make it traded separately, thereby transform risk into a “commodity”

(Steinherr, 2000, p. 101). Since risk as such is not desirable—in fact,

harmful—it becomes a “bad” not a “good” commodity, just like toxic

waste. From a social point of view, risk shall be minimized, not

promoted. Creating a market for risk, however, raises serious

questions on whether this would reduce risk or make it multiply. Since

market players seek profits, some players, particularly speculators, will

be better off if the market grows and expands. Speculation through

derivatives thrives on a growing market of risk, while producers and

consumers are better off if risk is minimized. The tension between the

two reflects the zero-sum nature of derivatives. Commoditizing risk

therefore is likely to make risk multiply and proliferate, making the

economy more risky and less stable. Moreover, just as toxic waste

might frequently end up buried in poor and less developed countries,

risk might end up born and suffered by poor and less developed

countries, with Asian and Latin American crises as clear examples.

The same applies with respect to individuals in a given country, where

ordinary people and taxpayers end up paying the real costs of


40 III. D ERIVATIVES

speculation (e.g. Steinherr, 2000, p. 91). Thus, commoditizing risk not

only makes it proliferate, but also disproportionately distributed.

Artificial Risks

         Derivatives allow for unbundling and repackaging risks in any

manner players find suitable for their preferences. But this feature

means that these instruments end up with risk-reward structures that

differ greatly from those of the underlying real assets (Tumpel-

Gugerell, 2003). This production of artificial risk profiles creates

arbitrage opportunities that are independent of real opportunities,

which opens the door to pure speculation to take advantage of these

artificial structures. Thus, as Tumpel-Gugerell (2003) rightly points

out, players are given, and frequently make use of, the opportunities of

pure speculative positions that are not related nor offered by the real

economy. In other words, artificial risk structures create artificial

arbitrage opportunities that can be exploited through pure speculation

with no connection to real economic activities. Pure speculation in

turn distorts assets prices, leading to negative impacts on real

investment opportunities. Consequently, capital committed to such

speculation becomes exposed to risks unrelated to the real economy.

Not only these risks are reflected back to the economy, they also

distort asset prices, leading to negative impacts on real investment

opportunities.


III. D ERIVATIVES 41

Severance of Risk

        Derivatives by construction separate and sever risk from

ownership and thus from real activities, as discussed above. Once risk

is separated from the real sector, there is no boundary on kinds of risk

traders may bet on, be it the rating of some selected companies, the

completion of a certain takeover, the weather in New York city, or any

other imaginable risk (e.g. Buffet, 2002). In addition, a derivative could

be derived from another derivative, not a real asset. Thus there are

options on futures, futures on options, options on options (Saber,

1999b, p. 122), etc. And all these compounded derivatives could be

based on market indices or volatilities, where no ownership of any sort

exists. This shows how derivatives diverge away from real activities

when they are severed from each other. Accordingly, their size and

growth move independent of the real sector. Since the real economy is

naturally more complex and is subject to more constraints than the

abstract world of risk, derivatives markets grow at a higher rate than

do real assets (LiPuma and Lee, 2005; Chorafas, 2003, p. 144). Given

the size of real resources committed to this huge market, derivatives

therefore expose real resources to risks that could have been avoided

in the first place.

        From this perspective, derivatives make the economy more

risky. As Lawrence Summers (1989) points out: “The freeing of

financial markets to pursue their casino instincts heightens the odds of

crises. … Because, unlike a casino, the financial markets are

inextricably linked with the world outside, the real economy pays the

price” (al-Yousef, 2005, p. 83).


42 III. D ERIVATIVES

Risk and Time

       Severance of risk in many aspects is similar to severance of

time from real transactions. Time and risk are highly inter-related,

and they are in fact two sides of the same coin (Bernstein, 1996, p. 15).

Severance of risk eventually leads to greater risks and higher costs of

risk management, as discussed earlier. The same happens when time is

separated from real transactions through interest-based lending. This

results in increasing levels of debt and thus higher costs of financing

through higher costs of debt services.

       Just as interest accumulates and compounds on past debts

leading to enormous divergence of finance from real activities,

derivatives similarly compound and multiply farther and farther from

real activities. And just as compounded interest costs the economy

much more than costs of real finance, derivatives cost the economy

much more than costs of real risks. Not surprisingly, interest-based

debt has been considered a major factor in facilitating speculation and

thus contributing to financial crises (Chapra, 2004).

Market Distribution

       The argument that severance of risk increases speculation is

supported by data on the distribution of market players. Number of

speculators in derivatives markets far exceeds that of hedgers. Data

also show that derivatives markets are highly concentrated in few

major banks, and most trading takes place among these banks.

       According to Office of Comptroller of the Currency (OCC),

only five commercial banks account for 96% of total notional amount


III. D ERIVATIVES 43

of derivatives in the commercial banking system in the U.S. Further,

only 2.7% of total derivatives are used by end users, i.e. corporations

assumed to hedge their risks, while the remaining 97.3% is used by

dealers (OCC, 2005). And according to the Bundesbank (2003), “less

than 10% of OTC transactions in derivatives is conducted with end

customers outside the financial sector” (p. 37). This shows that end

users, and thus hedgers, are minorities in the derivatives market.

Speculators dominate the market.

        Furthermore, according to Group of Thirty (1997), these

institutions dominating the market tend not just be each other’s

counterparties, but also to have extensive dealings with many of the

same customers, and be members of the same clearing houses and

exchanges. According to Tumpel-Gugerell (2003):

        This results in a random, zero-sum, large volume
        redistribution of wealth which affects all types of market
        participant, including those whose motivation was to
        invest in the real economy.

Further, the concentration of risks contributes to economic instability,

because if any of these large institutions get into difficulty the

contagion effect would be more serious and far reaching (Steinherr,

2000, pp. 190-193; Tickell, 2000, p. 91). The end result therefore is

that derivatives markets concentrate risks instead of diluting them, and

thus add to market instability rather than reduce it.


44 III. D ERIVATIVES

Law of Large Numbers

       The large number of speculators, it may be argued, helps

diversify and neutralize the risks they are bearing and thus helps

provide liquidity to the market. This could be true as long as these

risks are independent, as the law of large numbers requires. But if this

is not the case, risks might compound. Nobel laureate Kenneth Arrow

(1971) points to specialization of speculators to assume risks. He

explains:

       This specialization is a social gain, both because
       speculators normally have greater knowledge of the
       uncertainties than the average individual and because of
       the operation of the law of large numbers. However, if the
       speculators’ forecasts tend to be interdependent, this law,
       which depends upon the independence of the random
       events consolidated, may be inoperative and the situation
       may actually be worse than without speculation. (p. 24, emphasis
       added.)

Whether risks are independent or interlinked cannot be determined by

pure theory. Only history can give indications of the answer.

Observers generally agree that world markets are becoming more and

more interlinked. Asian crisis in 1997 and Russian crisis in 1998 each

had measurable impacts on Western markets. Derivatives by design

tend to interlink markets in increasingly unpredictable manners

(Steinherr, 2000, p. 158; Tickell, 2000, p. 90). The collapse of Long

Term Capital Management fund shows clearly how markets can

suddenly move in lockstep and away from “convergence” (Lowenstein,

2000, p. 144; Partnoy, 2003, p. 259).


III. D ERIVATIVES 45

        Consequently, risks of derivatives markets cannot be

considered independent. This is confirmed by “herding behavior,” i.e.

investors mimicking each other in the market. This behavior stems

from a variety of informational and psychological factors, and leads to

bubbles and crashes that cannot be accounted for by fundamentals

(Shiller, 2000; Sornette, 2003). Accordingly, speculators’ behavior

cannot be totally independent, and possibilities for unison movements

are highly likely. This raises concerns that speculators end up

exacerbating market risks rather than reducing them, as Arrow

pointed out.

Systemic Risk

        Advocates of derivatives argue that derivatives cannot make

the economy more risky since they are zero-sum trades, as mentioned

earlier. This implies that what one party loses is essentially what the

other party gains. There cannot be a net loss, and thus derivatives

cannot make the system worse off (Slutz, 2004).

        Critics, in contrast, point that this argument does not take into

account how zero-sum transactions affect aggregate variables.

Economic activities, particularly if leveraged, create a web of financial

relations among market participants. These relations interlink agents

with each other, such that the collapse of one agent would likely affect

many other agents beyond those with immediate contact. These links

make the market more efficient but at the same time more vulnerable

to external shocks.


46 III. D ERIVATIVES

        Positive-sum activities naturally create additional wealth. This

additional wealth would balance the additional risks created through

inter-linking of agents. In normal circumstance, the additional wealth

might well more than offset the additional risks. Consequently, the

economy becomes more efficient and more stable.

        In contrast, a market of zero-sum transactions by design does

not create additional wealth to balance the additional risks created

through inter-linking of agents. The system creates risks without

generating wealth to balance them. What starts as zero-sum at the

micro-level, ends up to be negative-sum at the macro-level. (More on

risk and zero-sum structure in section IV.)

        These arguments for systemic risks of derivatives are supported

by the realities of the markets. When the hedge fund Long Term

Capital Management (LCTM) was near collapse in 1998, with assets

exceeding $100 billions and more than $1 trillion in derivatives, the

Federal Reserve had to intervene to prevent a potential financial crisis.

According to Federal Reserve authorities, the failure could have

triggered the “worst financial crisis in half a century,” and that the

sudden liquidation of the fund in already unsettled markets “could well

have induced further financial dislocations around the world that

could have impaired the economies of many nations, including that of

the United States” (Partnoy, 2003, p. 261). This clearly shows how

derivatives may impair entire economies, as large as that of the U.S.

        Derivatives therefore might well make economies more volatile

and unstable. According to Bernstein (1996), despite the “ingenious”

tools created to manage risks, “volatilities seems to be proliferating


III. D ERIVATIVES 47

rather than diminishing” (p. 329). The data presented in the past

section show clearly that markets are becoming increasingly volatile. If

any thing, this shows that, overall, contribution of derivatives to

stability is questionable. Alfred Steinherr (2000), general manager of

the European Investment Bank, goes even farther:

        Recent financial history provides ample evidence that the
        growth of derivatives markets has made financial crises
        considerably more virulent, and the fast growth and
        widespread use of derivatives has increased the risk of
        financial disturbance (p. 177).

The Two Edges of Derivatives

        It is important to note that a derivative can be used for both

hedging and speculation alike. Intention does not impose any

structural difference on the used instrument. Consequently, a

company using a derivative for hedging might end up speculating, as

the nature of the instrument is identical for both uses (Saber, 1999a, p.

111). Kenneth Arrow (2003) notes that “derivatives and securities that

offer methods of reducing risks are not necessarily used for that

purpose. They are neutral and can be used to reduce risks, but people

gamble on them.” He adds: “That means speculators are adding to

the swings rather than reducing them.” Tumpel-Gugerell (2003) also

notes that: “It is impossible to distinguish between speculative

positions that are, in essence, bets, and positions that are triggered by

the resources allocation process of the real economy.”


48 III. D ERIVATIVES

        Accordingly, risk trading may divert corporations from their

real business to pure speculation, exposing real capital to major risks

totally unrelated to their normal business. This happened to a long list

of companies, see e.g. Bernstein (1996) and Partnoy (2003). As some

writers put it, “It seems that most farmers start speculating two years

or so of hedging” (Chance, 2003). Incentives to make money are

sufficiently strong that more than 97% of derivatives are used for

speculation. In this sense, derivatives are not really neutral.

Limits to Derivatives’ Protection

        It should be noted that derivatives are not risk free. They are

obligations, and as with any obligation, they carry their own risks:

counter party risk, operational risk, legal risk, etc. (e.g. Banks, 2004).

        Further, derivatives contracts commonly include a force majeure

clause that permits the parties to the contract to terminate it without

performance if an event occurs that has a pervasive effect on markets

(Steinherr, 2000, pp. 181, 89). This apparently explains why hedge

contracts did not help when Russia devalued its ruble and declared a

moratorium on its ruble-denominated treasury debt in 1998. Investors

faced huge losses despite their hedging contracts against the ruble. The

crisis caused a “flight to quality” since traditional hedge instruments

did not help. This eventually led to the collapse of Long Term Capital

Management fund, which threatened the global financial system

(Lowenstein, 2000). According to Steinherr (2000), “hedges may

evaporate in situations of severe market disruptions” (p. 199).


III. D ERIVATIVES 49

        Derivatives can be used to hedge specific risks, but it is rarely

possible to hedge every risk. According to Allan Kessler, vice president

of J.P. Morgan of foreign exchange, “There isn’t a company on earth

that has 100% hedging program” (Sparks, 2000). One example is the

case of the US subsidiary of Metallgessellschaft (MGRM). The

forward program of MGRM, although serves as a textbook hedge

model, caused huge losses to the company, which forced its board to

liquidate and close all its positions. Although the decision was

controversial, it was clear that a hedge strategy cannot be perfect, and

MGRM was not able to hedge all risks (Steinherr, 2000, p. 68).

        Since derivatives are marked to market, losses and gains on

derivatives have to be settled in cash daily, while overall value of the

hedge appears only at maturity. This means that for a hedge to be

effective, the agent has to be able to sustain short-term losses for a

prolonged period of time (ibid). If the agent has no sufficient funds, the

hedge fails. This also was one reason behind the collapse of LTCM,

where the fund was unable to survive short-term losses because of lack

of sufficient liquidity (Lowenstein, 2000).

        Derivatives are designed to deal only with known risks,

approximated with past performance and behavior. As Steinherr

(2000) points out: “The most important, and typically rare, future

events are most likely to be totally unanticipated today. Therefore

there is no hedge for them” (p. 104). Together with the force majeure

clause, derivatives’ hedging appears like an umbrella that works well

when the weather is clear, but fails when it rains.


50 III. D ERIVATIVES

       We shall see later that other strategies for hedging provide

better design and lower costs than derivatives do.

Who Ultimately Bears the Risk?

       Derivatives are highly leveraged by construction, as Greenspan

(2003) notes. This leverage makes the financial system highly

vulnerable. Greenspan makes it clear that managing the risks of such a

system “will not lie with the private sector alone.” He explains:

       Leveraging always carries with it the remote possibility of
       a chain reaction, a cascading sequence of defaults that will
       culminate in financial implosion if it proceeds unchecked.
       Only a central bank, with its unlimited power to create
       money, can with a high probability thwart such a process
       before it becomes destructive.

He thus points out that the burden of risk of extreme outcomes will be

“allocated between the public and private sectors.” In other words,

governments are the ones who eventually bear the risks of speculators.

According to Stiglitz (2002), speculators do not make money from

each other, as this is a highly risky activity that on average makes a

zero return. “What makes speculation profitable is the money coming

from governments” (p. 198). Greenspan admits the negative

consequences of such intervention, mainly moral hazard that might

make the system even riskier (Lowenstein, 2000, p. 230).

       The resulting allocation of risks of derivatives between private

and public sectors is rightly described as a system where ‘profits are

privatized, but losses are nationalized’ (Stiglitz, 2002, p. 209;

Chorafas, 2003, p. 135). The system rewards speculators but punishes


III. D ERIVATIVES 51

ordinary persons and businesses that were supposed to transfer their

risks to those same speculators. Instead of speculators bearing the risks

of ordinary agents (hedgers), the system makes hedgers eventually bear

the much greater risks of speculators. Steinherr (2000, p. 120) points to

costs of derivatives and who in fact pays them:

        As for an individual, so also for society, nothing comes for
        free. Yes, derivatives are a great social advance. The cost
        is much increased volatility, more frequent and vicious
        crises, less scope for government intervention. A price
        worth paying, probably, but still quite high. The major
        winners are those selling derivatives and many users.
        Those who pay [the price] are all market participants hit
        in a crash.

Winner and Losers in Derivatives

        Recall that a derivative is a zero-sum trade, and thus for each

contract there is a winner and a loser. There have many studies

conducted on some derivatives that examine numbers of winner and

losers, particularly among end users.

        One early study was by Hieronymus (1977), who examined

462 speculative accounts of a major futures brokerage firm. For less-

regular traders (beginners), they lost 92% of the time. Among regular

futures traders, he found that 41% made profits, while 59% lost.

Overall the market showed its zero-sum nature, as net profits for the

whole group were almost zero.

        Teweles and Jones (1987) review several studies with similar

results, and present their own. They examined about 4600 accounts of

a large brokerage firm for 10 years starting 1962. The results “confirm


52 III. D ERIVATIVES

that the average expectation of a trader making net profits in any

given year will be one in four” (p. 319). To make profits consistently

over several years, the probability drops significantly. The authors

estimate that, from the 25% who win in any given year, only 2% can

consistently win (p. 320).

        Moving to options world, Summa in 2003 examines the

records of Chicago Mercantile Exchange (CME). The study examines

expiring and exercised options covering the period 1997-1999. The

results show that 76% of all options held to expiration at CME expired

worthless (out of the money). The author concludes, “option sellers

had better odds than option buyers for positions held until expiration.”

        These results show that the majority of traders in options and

futures are more likely to lose. This adds another dimension of risk in

derivatives beyond those previously discussed.

Risk Dilemma

        The above discussion does not deny any value of derivatives.

After all, the Qur’�n points to some benefits of maysir or gambling:

“They ask you concerning wine and maysir. Say: In them is great sin as

well as benefits to people, but the sin is greater than the benefit”

(2:219).

        Derivatives    provide   value  through     management       and

distribution of risk. However, they are also perfect tools for gambling,

and consequently would distort incentives in a manner that defeat

their legitimate purpose. As Arrow (2003) points out, derivatives can

be used for reducing as well as compounding risk. Derivatives make


III. D ERIVATIVES 53

hedging and gambling undistinguishable. The question therefore is:

how can we obtain the benefits of hedging meanwhile avoid harmful

speculation? This issue is still not resolved, even though derivatives are

widely used.

        As discussed earlier, futures and options were considered

against the common law a century ago. Today, they are part of daily

economic life. This transition, according to Kreitner (2000), was not

achieved by changing the common law, or by discovering a formula to

differentiate legitimate risk taking from illegal wagering. What

happened is that “the question of gambling was eventually swallowed

and internalized, as if the problem were solved. However, no

analytical formula could distinguish gambling from risk allocation”

and that the contract law “stopped worrying and learned to love risk”

(p. 1096).

        The same dilemma arises in the economic arena. The

difference between arbitrage, that improves efficiency of the market,

and gambling, which destroys market fundamentals, was and still, a

subject of prolonged debate. Although it is easy to agree on the two

opposite extremes, no “analytical formula” is developed to filter out

the two in the vast majority of mixed situations in between.

        Further, economists are well aware of two sorts of incompatible

human behavior: Insurance and gambling. People purchase insurance

to avoid risk, but do gamble and thus volitionally take risks. There are

several attempts to explain this conflict (e.g. Arrow, 1971, pp. 22, 29;

Shapira, 1995, p. 11), but apparently the conflict is not yet resolved.

This again points to the two opposite extremes of risk. While there is a


54 III. D ERIVATIVES

human preference for risk taking, there is also a preference for risk

avoidance. How to distinguish desired risk-taking from abhorred risk

exposure is an age-old problem. The following sections explore the

Islamic approach for resolving this dilemma.


                                       IV
                         THE ISLAMIC APPROACH

More than 670 years go, Ibn Taymiah (728H – 1328G) wrote:

        Risk falls into two categories: commercial risk, where one
        would buy a commodity in order to sell it for profit, and
        rely on Allah for that. This risk is necessary for merchants,
        and although one might occasionally lose, but this is the
        nature of commerce.
              The other type of risk is that of gambling, which
        implies eating wealth for nothing (�WÉædÉf �ɪdG �cCG). This is
        what Allah and his Messenger (peace be upon him) have
        prohibited. ([2]; pp. 700-701.)

This phrase shows that Muslim scholars were aware of the dual forms

of risk. Although there might be cases where it is difficult to distinguish

between the two, the overall framework nonetheless is clear. The

above statement shows that there are two types of risk:

        1. Risk associated with normal economic transactions, i.e.
             value-adding and wealth-creating activities.
        2. Risk associated with “eating wealth for nothing”, or zero-
             sum activities, where no net additional wealth is created.

We shall address the first type of risk in this section, leaving the second

to the next section.


56 IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH

Risk in Islamic Economics

        If we define risk as possibility of loss, then it becomes clear

from an Islamic perspective that risk as such is not desirable. Islamic

principles clearly call for the preservation and development of wealth.

Exposing wealth to loss cannot be a goal in itself. In fact, al-Qarafi

clearly states that daman, i.e. protection of wealth, is desirable for

rational agents (cited in al-Suwailem [10]).

        This is the same position towards hardship (á�°ûe). Although

many Islamic deeds involve hardship of some sort, such hardship is

not desirable in itself. According to Ibn Taymiah ([4]; pp. 10:620-622):

        Reward of deeds is based on their usefulness, not their
        hardness. A good deed might be hard, but its goodness is
        for a reason other than being hard. Reward may be larger
        if involved hardship is larger, not because hardship is the
        objective of the deed, but because the deed implies
        hardship.

In other words, hardship is secondary in determining the value of the

deed. The primary factor is its usefulness. Accordingly, value would

reflect its hardness, but only to the extent that it is useful.

        The same reasoning applies to risk, as it is a form of hardship.

Risk as such is not desirable, although it is intrinsic to virtually all

economic activities. However, the value of an economic decision is not

determined primarily because of risks it involves; rather, it is determined

according to wealth it creates and value it adds. Risk is reflected in

value accordingly, but not that risk in its own determines the value.


IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH 57

       Whenever taking risk is praised it is because of the added value

and created wealth that follows, not that risk as such is desirable. This

represents a vital difference between legitimate and undesirable risk:

Risk is legitimate when it is necessary for value creating. But when no

value is added, it is a form of gambling.

Hedging

       Hedging is used generally to denote neutralizing and

minimizing risk. In this respect, it naturally belongs to Islamic

economic objectives. As such, this is not an issue and should not raise

any concerns. The issue, however, is how to reach this goal, and what

means is used to meat this end. If the means involves pure speculation

and gambling-like activities, it would be illegitimate, even if the

objective is. Ends do not justify means (Ibn al-Qayyim [6]), and thus

noble ends necessitate noble means. Obaidullah (2005) rightly notes,

“the provision of hedging facility is hardly an adequate rationale for

tolerating qim�r and maysir. The Shar�cah does not disapprove of

hedging, since it brings in some maslaha. It is the zero-sum nature of

                                     � �

the game that the Shar�cah finds objectionable, as in it lie the roots of

social disharmony and discord.” (p. 176.)

       To achieve legitimate hedging without maysir therefore is a

challenge that both Islamic and conventional finance are facing. The

objective of this paper is to explore and highlight milestones of the

Islamic approach through which legitimate means can be developed to

reach this essential goal.


58 IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH

Tolerable Risk

        Muslim scholars discussed the conditions under which risk can

be tolerated, and those under which it is not. Generally, they point

that risk is tolerable if it satisfies the following conditions:

        1. It is inevitable.
        2. It is insignificant.
        3. It is unintentional.

(See al-Dharir [12], pp. 587-612, and Hassan [7], pp. 464-469).

        The first condition implies that the same level of added value

of the concerned activity cannot be achieved without assuming risk of

loss or failure.

        The second condition concerns the degree of this risk. It states

that likelihood of failure shall be sufficiently small. Scholars were clear

that likelihood of failure should be less than that of success in order for

involved risk to be acceptable (al-Dharir, op. cit.). We shall see later

how this condition distinguishes the Islamic approach from

conventional, Neoclassical approach.

        The third condition follows from the first two. The objective of

a normal economic activity is the value it creates, not the risk it

necessitates. This risk therefore cannot be the intended part of the

transaction.

Inevitability of Risk

        The condition that risk shall be inevitable implies that risk is

inseparable from real, value-adding transactions. As discussed in the


IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH 59

last section, separating risk from real transactions creates even more

risks and makes the economy highly unstable.

        From Shar�cah point of view, exchange of pure liability for a

given price (Üɪ°†dG ��Y á°VhÉ©e) is unanimously prohibited (al-Suwailem,

1999). This is consistent with the general trend of Islamic finance to be

always linked to real transactions. Since derivatives by construction

separate risk from ownership and thus from real activities, they appear

in direct opposition to Shar�cah principles. Not surprisingly, several

Fiqh councils ruled that options and futures are unacceptable from

Shar�cah point of view (e.g. OIC Fiqh Council [14]).

        From an economic point of view, risk is necessary for economic

progress and wealth creation. According to Alan Greenspan:

        The willingness to take risk is essential to the growth of a
        free market economy. If all savers and their financial
        intermediaries invested only in risk-free assets, the
        potential for business growth would never be realized.
        (cited in Bernstein, 1996, p. 328.)

President of IMF, Horst Köhler (2004), reiterates this meaning:

“Indeed, it is the willingness to take risk and tackle uncertainty that

drives innovation and technical progress—and helps create jobs and

build prosperity.”

        Thus risk by nature is inseparable from economic activities.

Islamic requirements that risk may not be severed from real

transactions therefore are only natural and conform to economic

reality. Artificially severing risk will not make it disappear; rather, it

will come back in even more dangerous forms, as discussed earlier.


60 IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH

Likelihood of Failure

        It is clear from classical sources of fiqh that for risk to be

tolerable the likelihood of failure shall be less than that of success. This

is true regardless of the magnitude of the outcomes of the decision.

        This is in sharp contrast to expected utility rule (and many

competing rules for this matter), where decision is based on expected

terms, i.e. the product of probability of the outcome times its

magnitude. The difference between the two can be seen most clearly

in lotteries.

        In a lottery, an agent has an extremely small probability of

wining the prize. Probability of losing the ticket’s price is substantially

large. From an Islamic point of view, this cannot be acceptable since it

is almost certain that loss will materialize. Expected utility rule, in

contrast, is based on the expected value regardless of which state is

more likely to prevail. This is true even if probability of loss exceeds

99%, as long as the prize is sufficiently large. This rule leads to a kind

of “wishful behavior,” where an agent behaves according to his

preferences or wishes more than to objective reality.

        This kind of behavior is rightly described as deception and

delusion, or gharar. The decision maker is deceived by the size of the

prize such that he behaves as if it is more likely to obtain, when in fact

it is more likely not.

Causality

        The condition of dominant likelihood of success is equivalent

to saying that the action shall lead or “cause” the successful outcome


IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH 61

to materialize. A cause needs not lead to the final outcome with

certainty. It is sufficient that it does so more often than not (al-

Suwailem, 2002).

        From an Islamic perspective, uncertainty requires the decision

maker to take proper causes to achieve desirable results, and entrust

Allah to avoid possible but less likely failures. Taking proper causes is

viewed as mandatory and not merely preferable. Entrusting Allah thus

compliments rational decision-making and never substitutes for it.

Taking an action that is more likely to lead to failure is a violation of

Islamic teachings.

        This clearly shows that playing a lottery is not acceptable since

it is almost certain that the player will not win the prize and thus will

lose the price. This is also true for any economic decision for which

likelihood of failure dominates that of success.

Investment vs. Gambling

        The causality rule can clearly distinguish investment from

gambling. The key difference between the two is confidence of success.

An entrepreneur starts a project because he is confident that the

project would succeed. A gambler knows in advance that he is more

likely to lose than to win. However, the size of the prize deceives him

to engage into such a losing project.

        This difference is consistent with the concept of causality

according to Islamic principles. An action that leads to failure more

frequently than success cannot be considered as a cause of success. It is

a cause of failure.


62 IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH

        Expected utility rule in contrast does not differentiate between

a cause and a non-cause. It mixes the likelihood of the outcome with

its magnitude, and decision is based on the final product. No attention

is given to how the outcome is reached, whether systematically or by

blind luck. This is not the way agents normally evaluate their

decisions. According to Ben-Ner and Putterman (1998):

        Individuals care about the manner in which they
        themselves and others behave, including the ways in
        which they attain outcomes of interest. ... Uncommon is
        the individual who is indifferent about whether he has
        achieved his income through honest work or blind luck,
        whether he has cheated others or treated them fairly. (p.
        20)

Choice under Uncertainty

        Conventional theories of choice, most obviously expected

utility, cannot distinguish investment from gambling. Rather, decision

under uncertainty is viewed simply as a choice among lotteries (e.g.

Varian, 1992, and Jehle, 1991). Not only this is inconsistent with the

Islamic view, it is also inconsistent with real decision making in

business environments.

        Studies by MacCrimmon and Wehrung (1986) and Shapira

(1995) show that business managers rarely take risk as given. They

consistently attempt to adjust risks such that they are confident of the

successful outcome. According to Shapira: “Managers see themselves

as taking risks, but only after modifying and working on the dangers so

that they can be confident of success” (p. 74; emphasis added). In this


IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH 63

context, risk taking “is an endeavor where a manager can use his

judgment, exert control, and utilize skills”. This is absent from

gambling (p. 48). Shapira concludes that the “gambling metaphor

appears as an inadequate description of managerial risk taking” (p.

120). James March, decision scientist at Stanford University, writes:

         Although theories of choice tend to treat gambling as a
         prototypic situation of decision making under risk,
         decision makers distinguish between “risk taking” and
         gambling, saying that while they should take risks, they
         should never gamble. They react to variability more by
         trying actively to avoid it or control it than by treating it as
         a tradeoff with expected value in making a choice. (1994,
         p. 54)

These results point to the fundamental difference between risk taking

associated with real business activities, and gambling where likelihood

of failure is dominant, but the size of the outcome deceptively makes

the choice acceptable.

A Causal Decision Rule

         If we want to amend the expected utility rule in the light of the

above discussion, one way to do so is to impose a constraint on the

likelihood of success. Suppose that an action a would lead to outcome

x i � 0 in state i , i =1, ..., n , with probability pi . Probabilities could

be objective or subjective, as long as they satisfy axioms of probability.

Let v(x i ) be the payoff (utility) function of the decision maker in state

i , and let c(a) be the cost of action a. Expected utility requires an

action a is admissible as long as:


64 IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH

                    n

[1] U (a) = � pi v(x i ) � c � 0 .

                   i=1

For example, the action could be to purchase a lottery ticket for which

the prize is, say, one million, and c =1 is the price of the ticket. Then

the outcomes are either to win the prize, whereby x1 =1000,000 , or

not, whereby x2 = 0 . The action is admissible as long as the expected

payoff is non-negative. If the probability of winning is one in million,

and the payoff function is linear, then we have:

v1 =1,000,000 , v2 = 0 , c =1 , p1 = 1,000,0001

                                               , p2 = 1,000,000
                                                        999,999
                                                                .

Consequently, U (a) = 0 . Thus, purchasing the ticket would be

admissible. To exclude this sort of behavior, we have to impose a

restriction on admissible probabilities. This can be achieved by

subjecting [1] to the constraint that probabilities of success are larger

than those of failure. Let S be the set of outcomes for which

v(x i ) � c � 0 , and let S � be its compliment, i.e. for which v(x i ) � c < 0 .

The set S represents the set of successful outcomes, while S �

represents unsuccessful ones. Then action a is admissible as long as:

                    n

[2] U (a) = � pi v(x i ) � c � 0 , and

                   i=1

[3] �i�S

               pi > � pi .
                     i�S �


IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH 65

The constraint [3] requires that total probability of success exceeds

that of failure. Since total probability of all outcomes equals one, then

condition [3] is equivalent to requiring that � pi > 0.5 for i � S .

This condition therefore excludes outcomes with low probabilities that

might be chosen merely because of the associated large payoffs, i.e.

gambling.

Statistical Measure

         A more direct representation of the causal rule can be obtained

by invoking statistical measures of probability distribution. The

expected utility rule is equivalent to the mean of the payoffs

distribution. The mean is a measure of the central tendency of the

distribution, defined as the sum of the values of the random variable

weighted by their respective probabilities.

         An alternative measure is the median. The median is commonly

defined as the point that divides total distribution into two equal parts,

each with probability of 50%. A more general definition, suitable for

both discrete as well as continuous distributions, is provided by

DeGroot (1986, p. 207). The median is defined as a value m of a

random variable x� such that:

[4] prob( x� � m) � 0.5 and prob( x� � m) � 0.5 .

That is, the probability distribution on either side of the median is at

least 0.5. The two sides therefore need not be equal. For the outcomes

of a given action a, the median payoff v̂ is defined as:


66 IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH

[5] prob(v( x� ) � v̂) � 0.5 and prob(v( x� ) � v̂) � 0.5 .

A decision rule based on the median would require that an action a is

admissible if the median payoff is non-negative, i.e.:

[6] U (a) = v̂ � c � 0 .

To apply this rule to the lottery example, recall that there are two

payoffs (assuming linearity of v ):

         v1 =1,000,000 with p1 = 1,000,000 1
                                                 , and
         v2 = 0 with p2 = 1,000,000
                                 999,999
                                         .

The median of this distribution is v2 , since it satisfies the conditions in

[5]. To see this, note that prob(v( x� ) � v2 ) = p2 . That is, probability to

get at most a zero-payoff (which is the smallest payoff) is greater than

0.5. Next, prob(v( x� ) � v2 ) =1 . That is, a player is certain to get zero or

more. (The reader may want to verify that v1 violates [5] and thus

cannot be a median.) Since the median is zero, the utility of

purchasing a lottery ticket becomes negative, and therefore the

decision is not admissible.

        Note that this result is obtained regardless of the shape of the

utility function. This makes the median rule robust with respect to the

specification of risk preferences of the decision maker. Statistically, it is

well known that the median is more stable than the mean, and


IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH 67

represents the central tendency of the distribution more accurately

(DeGroot, 1986, pp. 208-209).

        It is somewhat surprising that while the median is more robust

than the mean, it is also more consistent with Islamic and moral

principles regarding wagering and gambling. The rule succeeds, at

least to some extent, in distinguishing acceptable risk taking from

gambling, a problem that puzzled lawmakers and economists alike.

The median rule is consistent with results of evolutionary game theory,

which point that “nature abhors low probability events” (Gintis, 2000,

p. 117). From an evolutionary point of view, low probability events

add little to agents’ fitness, and thus are evolutionarily unimportant.

Since few studies examine the median as a decision rule under

uncertainty, further investigation is needed to explore and better

understand its implications.

Derivatives
        As discussed earlier, trading derivatives, such as futures and

options, results in losses more than 70% of the time. Since likelihood

of failure exceeds that of success, such instruments are considered as

factors of loss, not of gain, which violates condition [3] above. Further,

using the median rule in [6], the decision to trade derivatives becomes

inadmissible. Only in expected terms might they appear profitable.

But the expected utility rule is questionable, both from an Islamic

perspective as well as real business decision-making, as explained

earlier.


68 IV. T HE ISLAMIC APPROACH

       From the above discussion, none of the requirements of

tolerable risks are satisfied by derivatives. This raises deep questions

about Islamic legitimacy of these instruments.

       The fact that derivatives by design are zero-sum games is

another dimension of the subject that will be treated in the following

section.


                                  V
                        THEORY OF GHARAR

The word gharar in Arabic language means risk. It also has the

meaning of deception and delusion (al-Dharir [12]). The two

meanings coincide most clearly in prospects with low probability but

large magnitude, as in lotteries and all forms of gambling. The size of

the payoff entices the agent to engage into an almost losing game. This

is the essence of gambling that conventional choice rules fail to

exclude, as discussed earlier.

       While the previous section focused on individual decision-

making, this section focuses on bilateral or interactive decisions. In

such interactions gharar takes a definitive structure. It becomes

equivalent to a zero-sum game with uncertain payoffs (al-Suwailem,

1999). This structure is consistent with Shar�cah measures of gharar.

The measure can be used as a basis for evaluating as well as

developing risk management instruments consistent with Shar�cah, as

will be discussed below.

Types of Games

       The term “game” is used for a variety of settings and

arrangements. Here it is used to denote a for-profit exchange among


70 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

two or more agents, whereby agents’ payoffs are uncertain at the

beginning of the game.

       Games can be classified according to the sum of players’

payoffs into three categories: positive-sum, zero-sum, or mixed-sum

games.

       1. Positive-sum games are games in which players have

common interests, and thus they gain together or lose together (see

Figure 7). Since agents are assumed to be rational, the losing outcome

will not be their objective of the game. The positive outcome therefore

is the objective of the game, and for this reason it is described as a

positive-sum game.

       In Figure 7, (A , B) denotes players of the game. The right

branch denotes the positive payoffs for each (the first is the payoff of A

while the second is that for B). The left branch denotes negative

payoffs. At the start of the game, it is not known which branch they

will arrive at. However, each player is assumed to seek the positive

outcome rather than the negative one, and thus the objective of the

game becomes mutual gain. If agents follow the median rule discussed

earlier, then the positive outcome will be more likely to materialize.

This makes the game Pareto-optimal, since both players are likely to

be better off playing the game compared to not playing it.

       An example of a positive-sum game is partnership or
musharakah. Since each partner contributes capital and labor, both

would gain if the project succeeds, and both would lose if it fails.


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 71

                                   (A , B)
          (– , –)                                        (+ , +)
                     Figure 7: Positive-sum Games

Note that the size of the payoffs need not be equal for the two parties.

But the sign must be identical; that is, they gain together and lose

together, although the contribution of each might not be equal.

       2. Zero-sum games are games in which one party gains and the

other loses (Figure 8). Gambling is the most obvious example: Two

players put, say, 1000 each, and a coin is thrown. If it comes head, A

wins 2000, otherwise B wins.

                                  (A , B)
          (+ , –)                                       (– , +)
                       Figure 8: Zero-sum Games

Obviously, there is no possibility that the two could both win. One

player wins only at the expense of the other. Again, the magnitudes of

gain and loss need not be equal. The term “zero-sum” indicates that

the interests of players are in direct opposition. As textbooks on game


72 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

theory show, such games can always be reformulated so that the

payoffs add to zero (Friedman, 1990, pp. 79-80; Binmore, 1994, pp.

276-277). We shall use the term “zero-sum game” to indicate games of

direct opposition, regardless of the size of payoffs. Zero-sum games are

Pareto-inferior, since they do not allow mutual gain of players. Agents

are better off not playing the game (al-Suwailem, 1999).

       3. Mixed games are games that include both sorts of outcomes:

the zero-sum outcome as well as the positive-sum outcome (Figure 9).

                                    (A , B)
           (+ , –)                                       (+ , +)
                           Figure 9: Mixed Games

These games allow for mutual gain, but also imply the possibility of

conflict of interest. Examples of mixed-games include sharecropping

or muzara c ah, ja c alah, and c urbun (see al-Suwailem, 1999). In fact,

most economic activities are mixed or non-zero-sum games, as

Schelling (1980) points out. Life therefore is not a gamble, as many

writers claim. It is a mixed game that could end up in conflict or in

cooperation. Wright (2000) argues that evolution, both social and

biological, progresses towards non-zero-sum interactions. We shall see


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 73

later how the structure of mixed games can be useful in developing

Islamic hedge instruments.

Measure of Gharar

        In a zero-sum game, one party gains at the expense of the

other. It is a pure transfer of wealth for no counter-value. Since each

party is seeking profits not donations, it becomes therefore a sort of

“eating wealth for nothing,” strictly condemned in the Qur’�n.

Further, a zero-sum game is a game with direct conflict of interests,

which represents the source of enmity that accounts for the prohibition

of maysir or gambling in the Qur’�n: “Satan only wants to plant enmity

and hatred among you through wine and maysir” (6:91).

        On the other hand, gambling represents the purist form of

gharar (al-Dharir [12], p. 622). Since gambling is obviously a zero-sum

game, it follows that gharar must be unacceptable to the extent that it

possesses the zero-sum structure. Accordingly, the circle of gharar is

wider than that of gambling. For this reason, some transactions might

contain gharar (i.e. a zero-sum outcome) but they are still acceptable if

it the zero-sum component is dominated by the positive component, as

in sharecropping and ja c alah.

        From Shar�cah point of view, generally speaking, the

acceptability of such mixed games depends on the likelihood of the

cooperative, positive-sum, outcome. If this outcome is dominant, the

game generally is acceptable. In this case, the zero-sum outcome is

considered as “minor gharar.” If the zero-sum outcome is dominant, it

becomes “excessive gharar” and thus not acceptable.


74 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

         Technical formulation of this measure, as well as detailed

discussion of several examples and applications, is provided in al-

Suwailem (1999).

Characteristics of Zero-sum Games

         Although it might appear fuzzy, the zero-sum property, in its

basic form, is quite clear: Whatever one party gains is what the other

loses. The following points help clarify how this structure applies to

different forms of transactions.

         1. First, note that in any zero-sum game, uncertainty at the

time of contract is an essential condition. If it were known upfront, the

game would not have been played. For example, if it were known on

which side the coin will land, there is no point of betting. This is not

the case in games with mutual gain. In a normal sale, where relevant

variables are known upfront, the sale takes place with full information.

Even if all future information were known at the beginning, the sale

will still be performed if it satisfies the needs of the two parties.

         2. It should be noted also that gains and losses in a zero-sum

game are determined bilaterally, i.e. between the two parties of the

contract. That is, an actual net transfer of wealth takes place at

maturity from one party to the other, with no counter-value in

exchange. If one buys a good on spot basis, and its price subsequently

falls, this loss is not a direct gain to the first seller, except as foregone

losses. But contractually, no counter party has these losses credited to


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 75

his account as gains, and thus no net transfer of wealth takes place.

Although trading of shares or commodities might at times appear as a

zero-sum game, it is only at the system level. Individually, however,

spot trading, with predetermined prices and parameters, cannot be a

zero-sum game since the relationship between the two parties ends the

moment the trade is concluded. Only in presence of uncertainty

during the contract that a zero-sum exchange might, but not

necessarily, arise.

       3. Derivatives are clear examples of zero-sum games. They are

obligations to exchange certain amounts of money in a future date.

The difference between prices at the time of contract and at maturity

is debited from one party and credited to the other, and that is why

they are called contracts for differences. With mark-to-market system,

this is done on daily basis. Even if the derivative is traded in a

secondary market, the obligation as such survives throughout the life

of the contract, and whoever becomes party to it has to settle these

differences.

       4. Financial markets as a whole might appear at times as zero-

sum systems. Pyramid schemes are also zero-sum systems. But this

applies to the system as a whole, not to individual contracts as such.

Zero-sum systems arise because of misuse of normal, non-zero-sum

contracts. However, with zero-sum contracts, the system by design will

have a zero-sum structure. That is, systems of zero-sum contracts are


76 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

zero-sum overall, but systems of non-zero-sum contracts may or may

not be zero-sum overall.

        For this reason the Prophet, peace be upon him, has put

further conditions on normal sale, e.g. not to sell before possession or

to sell what one doesn’t have. These conditions help make the system

overall positive-sum and prevent what Shiller (2000) calls “naturally

occurring Ponzi processes” (pp. 64-67). During speculative bubbles,

the market as a whole behaves as a Ponzi scheme: early investors get

returns from newcomers, and newcomers profit from those joining

afterwards, and so on, but latecomers eventually bear the cost when

the market crashes. While financial markets in principle are useful and

provide important economic functions, they need to be regulated in

order to minimize such Ponzi processes from taking over. For

example, James Tobin (1978) and Lawrence and Victoria Summers

(1989) propose a transaction tax to reduce frequent trading and thus to

curb speculation. Allais (1993) calls for abandoning continuous

quotation of prices, and having a single quotation per day. He also

insists that margins on forwards should be considerably increased to

avoid harmful speculation (p. 36). Recall that in Islamic forwards, i.e.

salam, the full price must be paid in advance, which points to the

economic rationale for this condition. Detailed discussion of financial

markets reform is beyond the scope of this paper, but the point should

be clear: non-zero-sum contracts might lead to Ponzi, zero-sum

systems if not properly regulated.


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 77

        The above discussion hopefully clarifies the difference between

zero-sum contracts and zero-sum systems. The former implies the

latter, but the opposite is not necessarily true.

Expected vs. Actual Measures

        The zero-sum measure is based on actual, realized outcomes of

the transaction. Derivatives and all forms of gambling are zero-sum

games in this respect. In expected terms, however, they might be

considered as mutual gain deals. In other words, they might be win-

win games ex ante, but win-lose ex post. The two measures are clearly

incompatible, and thus a choice must be made between the two.

        Economic success obviously is based on, and measured in

terms of, actual and realized performance. In expected terms, LTCM

might have been a profitable investment. In early 1998, the fund’s

value-at-risk (VAR), which measures the maximum daily loss in any

single day with 95% confidence, was less than 1% of its capital. The

probability that the fund would lose all its capital within a year was

10�24 . That is, it would take several multiples of the lifetime of the

universe for this event to occur (Lowenstein, 2000, p. 159; Partnoy,

2003, p. 257). Few months later, the fund collapsed when losses wiped

out most of its capital. In other words, failure also is measured in ex

post terms. Bankruptcy is decided according to actual, not expected,

results. Similarly, profits and losses of derivatives are calculated daily

through marking to market, not based on the overall, expected, value

of the contract. Consequently, whenever expected and actual

measures are in conflict, the latter obviously will have the precedence.


78 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

        This is supported by the nature of uncertainty. Uncertainty

reflects our ignorance of the reality. It therefore exists only in human

minds. In reality, things either exist or do not exist. Nothing in the

outside universe is random or undetermined. “God does not play

dice,” as Albert Einstein famously affirmed (Pais, 1982). The Qur’�n

clearly states: “Verily all things We created in (precise) amount”

(54:49), “And every single thing is before Him in (due) proportion”

(13:8). Uncertainty and risk therefore cannot exist outside human

mind.

        Accordingly, risk per se is not in fact traded, as it cannot exist

in reality. What is actually traded is money for money. Kenneth Arrow

(1971) points to this fact with respect to commercial insurance. He

describes it as an “exchange of money for money, not money for

something which directly meets needs.” (p. 134.) Since this exchange is

contingent on a certain event, the contract ends up in payment in one

direction only. If the event occurs the insurer pays to the insured more

than the latter has paid, and thus the net-payment becomes money for

nothing. The opposite is true if the event does not occur. In either

state one party pays something for nothing. Only in expected terms

that there is a mutual exchange. Ex post, however, no mutual

exchange takes place, and it becomes a sort of eating wealth for

nothing.

        This clearly reflects the discrepancy between actual and

expected measures in case of zero-sum games. This discrepancy is

closely related to that between the mean and the median discussed

earlier. The discrepancy arises in case of “outliers,” i.e. outcomes with


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 79

low likelihood but large magnitude. It is such cases where gambling

arises, and the need for careful discrimination of types of risk is called

for. The zero-sum measure provides an important landmark in

achieving this objective.

Risk and Zero-sum Structure

        There are several reasons why a zero-sum market is more risky

than a normal market:

        1. Earlier we argued that a zero-sum market does not create

additional wealth to balance the additional risks created through

interaction of agents. This is particularly true when the market is

highly leveraged, as it is the case with respect to derivatives.

        2. A zero-sum structure by design is relative: The payoff of one

agent is the negative of the other. Relative payoff makes agents’

behavior highly sensitive to each other. Consequently, a feedback loop

is created as changes in an agent’s behavior feeds back to itself through

the behavior of others. The positive feedback loop and recursiveness of

the system makes it increasingly nonlinear and thus prone to chaotic

episodes, as several writers have pointed out (Sornette, 2003; Tumpel-

Gugerell, 2003; Mandelbrot and Hudson, 2004; Bennett, 2004).

        3. A derivative by design is derived from an underlying asset or

variable. Movements in this variable would register profits for one

party and equal losses to the other. In a zero-sum market, where all

transactions are zero-sum games, any change in relevant economic


80 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

variables will necessarily create losses to some parties. The market has

no room for mutual gain and common reward. Since risk is defined in

terms of exposure to loss, a zero-sum market almost by definition

becomes more risky than a normal one.

       For example, in a futures market of a certain commodity, any

change in the price of the commodity registers profits to one party and

equal losses to the other. In a salam contract, in contrast, the price is

paid in full in advance. The advanced payment provides the seller the

possibility to utilize it in a manner that could compensate for moderate

price increases of the commodity. On the other hand, since delivery is

destined to a future date, the paid price is lower than the spot price.

This discount provides a cushion for the buyer against moderate price

declines. Therefore, the advanced payment provides a “safety margin”

for both parties against moderate price fluctuations. This is in contrast

to leveraged futures, where any price fluctuations presents a gain to

one party and a loss to the other (al-Suwailem, 1999, pp. 84-85).

       As another example, consider companies that provide their

employees options to buy shares of the company at a predetermined

price. Rise in the share’s price above that given to employees is a gain

to the employee and a cost to the company. However, this cost is

utilized as an incentive to employees, so the final result of the contract

is a win-win outcome (notwithstanding possible misuses of stock

options). That is, wealth created through employee’s effort

compensates for the loss arising from the increase in the share’s price.

In contrast, in a call option, any changes in the price of the underlying

will register gains to one party and losses to the other.


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 81

        Derivatives deliberately sever wealth-creating activities from

risk management, making them by construction zero-sum games. A

derivative contract does not require the creation of wealth that

balance the losses involved. The argument that risk trading promotes

value-creating activities, if true, reinforces the Islamic position, since

integrating the two will not be harmful. The integration would

produce effectively the same result, but provides better incentives to do

so.

        4. In a zero-sum market all players are in direct conflict. This

results in players taking advantage of each other when economic

variables move unfavorably to some. Thus the likelihood of failure of

inflicted players will rise beyond that determined by exogenous

economic forces. This apparently what happened to LTCM, when

investors became aware of the losses the fund suffered after the crisis of

Russian bonds and other emerging markets in 1998. Traders started

betting against LTCM, causing further losses to the fund. In the words

of Partnoy (2003, p. 260): “Other traders smelled blood at LTCM,

and began betting against the hedge fund, trying to weaken its

positions.” LTCM was acting as “bank of volatility,” and thus suffered

“a classic run.” According to Lowenstein (2000): “It made no

difference whether banks were consciously trying to profit at Long-

Term’s expense or merely protecting themselves … Either motivation

would have produced the same behavior” (p. 174, emphasis original). The fact

that investors while protecting themselves necessarily attacked LTCM

is a characteristic feature of zero-sum games. Since interests were in


82 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

direct opposition, the benefit of one party necessarily implies the harm

of the other.

       Together with moral hazard, this shows that incentives react to

the payoff structure in a manner that might distort behavior and thus

create additional layers of risk to the system.

       Since the zero-sum structure creates unnecessary risks, it

becomes consistent with a widely held view that gambling is

characterized by involving artificial risks (e.g. Borna and Lowery,

1987; Raines and Leathers, 1994). The zero-sum structure therefore is

a sufficient condition to consider a certain transaction as gambling

regardless of the tools used to implement it.

Two Measures of Gharar

       In the last section we argued that taking risk would be

acceptable, in a real transaction, if success was more likely than failure.

A deal that is more likely to fail is more of a gamble than an

investment. It is therefore a form of gharar. Here we argued that gharar

is a predominantly zero-sum game. That is, we have two measures of

gharar:

1. The likelihood measure.

2. The zero-sum measure.

The first is related to individual decisions, while the second is related

to interactive decisions. But how these two measures are related to

each other?


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 83

        First, note that in a zero-sum game, there is no way that both

players could win with probability greater than 0.5. Suppose that one

player is likely to win with probability 70%. Since it is a zero-sum

game, then if one party wins the other must lose. This means that the

other player must lose with probability 70%. That is, a zero-sum game

does not allow success to be more likely for both players. Thus the

zero-sum measure implies the likelihood measure.

        Next, the likelihood measure in principle is more general the

zero-sum measure. To see this, consider an investment decision that

has negligible chances to payoff. For example, a speculator decides to

build a shopping mall in uninhabited area. Although the contract with

the construction agent is a legitimate transaction, in terms of its final

objectives it is a gamble on the side of the speculator. Thus, a

legitimate, real transaction could be used for illegitimate purposes.

This shows that the likelihood measure is broader than the zero-sum

measure.

        However, in a competitive economy, such highly risky

decisions would eventually be transformed into zero-sum games. If an

investor is willing to spend money for a highly risky project, then

another agent would step in and offer to take less money in exchange

for a higher return but with low likelihood. Ex ante, both parties are

better off, and thus highly risky projects cannot continue for a long

time. Accordingly, the likelihood measure, while pertain to individual

decision-making, naturally leads to the zero-sum measure.

        The two types of gharar might help clarify two widely used, but

still ambiguous, terms: speculation and gambling. We might describe


84 V. THEORY OF GHARAR

the first type of gharar as “speculation,” and the second type as

“gambling.” Speculation thus is to use a legitimate contract for highly

risky purposes. It describes a mixed game where the zero-sum

outcome is more likely to obtain. Gambling, on the other hand,

implies a stronger connotation, as both parties are involved in direct

conflict or a strictly zero-sum game. From the above discussion,

speculation eventually transforms into gambling. Further, speculation,

in this context, transforms a market of non-zero-sum contracts to a

zero-sum system, like Ponzi or pyramid schemes.

Value of Risk Management

        As point out earlier, hedging is valuable and consistent with

Islamic economic objectives. However, conventional instruments,

mainly derivatives, cannot separate hedging from speculation. They

are used indistinguishably for both purposes, but mostly, 97%, for

speculation. How can we realize the value of hedging and risk

management without incurring the increasing costs of speculation?

        From an Islamic perspective, the answer may not be very

difficult. Islamic rules of exchange, being revealed from Allah (s.w.t)

and thus entail His perfect wisdom and knowledge, provide the right

framework for achieving this challenging objective. The general

principle, which is a matter of consensus, is that risk cannot be severed

and separated from real transactions. This will make risk transfer a

zero-sum game and thus a form of eating wealth for nothing, which is

strictly and explicitly prohibited by the Qur’�n (e.g. 2:188, 3:29).


V. THEORY OF GHARAR 85

       To achieve desirable risk transfer, therefore, we have to utilize

structures that allow for mutual gain, i.e. nonzero-sum games. Such

games, while imply the possibility of a zero-sum outcome, permit a

positive-sum outcome, and thus provide a room for mutual benefits.

This is the general strategy for developing risk management tools that

are consistent with Islamic principles. The following sections attempt

to implement this strategy.


                                         VI
                          FINANCIAL ENGINEERING:
                          AN ISLAMIC PERSPECTIVE

The term “financial engineering” has many connotations, and might

have different meanings in different contexts (Marshall and Bansal,

1992). In conventional financing, it relates mostly to derivatives. But

the term is broader than that. For Islamic finance, the concept takes a

special importance, as we shall see.

Definition and Concept

         According to Finnerty (1988, 1994), financial engineering

involves the “design, development and implementation of innovative

financial instruments and processes, and the formulation of creative

solutions to problems in finance.” The objectives of financial

engineering are to lower transaction costs and achieve better returns

(Merton, 1992).

         Innovation by nature is unpredictable. If it were, it is no longer

innovative. Thus, attention should be directed towards tools and

techniques that facilitate innovation and creativity. Financial

engineering therefore can be better described as: principles and strategies

for developing innovative financial solutions.


88 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

        The difference between tools for innovation and innovation

itself is emphasized by de Bono (1970). He coined the term “lateral

thinking” to describe thinking strategies and techniques that permit

and encourage creativity. Creativity therefore is a consequence rather

than the subject of analysis. Similarly, financial engineering should be

concerned with tools and techniques for developing creative

instruments and innovative products (see also Mason et. al., 1995, p.

xiii).

        From an Islamic point of view, there are Shar�cah principles

that should be observed for developing financial products. Thus the

definition emphasizes both principles and strategies for financial

innovation.

        The definition mentions financial solutions rather than

instruments or contracts (al-Suwailem [8]). This highlights the added

value of innovation. A “solution” is something that satisfies a genuine

need that was not possible before. This is general enough to include

processes, instruments, or products that result in better efficiency and

returns, as emphasized by Merton (1992). According to Mason et. al.

(1995), financial engineering shall not be measured by the complexity

of mathematical models involved or of the legal documents required.

Rather, it is measured by the expanded economic and managerial

flexibility it offers (p. xiii).

Value of Innovation

        Innovation is a change, and change creates instability.

Instability obviously is not desirable, and thus innovation in itself is not


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 89

a goal. Only when innovation creates value, which offsets the

instability it creates, that it becomes desirable. Innovation therefore is

a tool and a means for generating value. Mason et. al. (1995) rightly

note that relevance of financial innovation is measured by its impact

on the effectiveness of the financial system, not by its novelty. Leathers

and Raines (2004) point to the negative effects of derivative

innovations, and that such innovations are inconsistent with the

Schumpeterian view of creative destruction. This confirms the need

for innovations within a different framework and in a different

direction.

Shar�cah and Creativity

        Shar�cah provides a comprehensive set of rules governing and

guiding human behavior. Although these rules restrain behavior in

many respects, this does not hinder creativity. In fact, the opposite is

more likely to be true, since creativity is stimulated by constraints.

Elster (2000) shows how and why rational agents in some cases might

be better off when they have fewer options. In such cases, less is more,

which has been supported by many experimental studies (Gigerenzer

et al., 1999). Elster also shows how artists, for instance, deliberately

choose to restrain themselves in order to be more creative. Silber

(1983) provides evidence that constraints were a major force behind

financial innovations that improved economic performance and

welfare.

        Thus, constraints need not hinder creativity. This is especially

true with respect to Divine rulings. Such rulings imply the ultimate


90 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

wisdom of Allah (s.w.t.), and their observance therefore will only

improve human life. Islamic teachings in general provide the right

environment for valuable creativity and innovation. The Qur’�n

frequently emphasizes reflecting and pondering upon signs of truth,

and condemns those who blindly follow inherited culture even if it

contradicts the facts. Again, contrarious thinking is not necessarily a

virtue in itself, but a means to discover the truth and avoid deceitful

perceptions.

Regulatory Arbitrage

       Merton Miller (1986) argues that a major impulse for financial

innovation is to avoid regulation. Given the increasingly globalized

financial markets, investors face different regulatory environments.

This creates an opportunity to overcome local regulations using

suitably designed instruments (mostly derivatives) issued across the

boarders. Free-market advocates particularly see regulations hindering

economic efficiency, and thus consider circumventing regulations via

financial innovation as a means to restore market efficiency (Partnoy,

1997).

       This might be relevant for outdated or artificial regulations

that serve little or no social function. However, regulation in principle

serves a crucial role in stabilizing the market and minimizing systemic

dangers. Regulations regarding disclosure and capital requirements,

for example, are essential for self-discipline and risk control.

Circumventing such regulations, through financial innovation and


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 91

accounting manipulation, very likely leads to undesirable

consequences, with Enron and similar episodes as visible examples.

        Similarly, from an Islamic point of view, circumventing

Shar�cah principles would negatively affect market performance and

jeopardize objectives of Islamic finance in the first place. More on this

point later in this section.

State of Financial Innovation

        Professor Peter Drucker (1999) argues that financial-services

industry is now declining. The reason, he writes, is simple: “The

dominant financial-services institutions have not made a single major

innovation in 30 years.” Instead of inventing new services to

customers, financial firms are mostly trading for their own accounts,

thus involved in a “zero-sum game,” since the gain of one firm is the

loss of the other. The only innovations during the past three decades,

he argues, have been “allegedly ‘scientific’ derivatives,” which are no

more scientific than systems used in Monte Carlo or Las Vegas. “As a

result, the industry’s products have become commodities and

increasingly both less profitable and more expensive to sell.”

        Drucker argues that there are now three possible roads the

industry can take. The easiest is to keep the current practices and

trends. The industry may survive, but will continue to decline. The

second is for the industry “to be replaced by innovating outsiders and

newcomers.” The third is for the industry players “to become

innovators themselves and their own ‘creative destroyers’.” With the

increasing change in world economy, the first road is not really an


92 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

option. Thus, the industry either changes itself, or outsiders will do so.

Not surprisingly, he titles his article: “Innovate or die.”

        This points that the Islamic industry has a good opportunity at

this stage to provide genuine and value-adding financial services that

the industry is seriously lacking.

Principles of Islamic Financial Engineering

        From an Islamic perspective, we can identify four principles for

financial engineering, two concern objectives: principle of balance and

principle of integration, and two concern methodology: principle of

acceptability and principle of consistency.

Principle of Balance

        This principle reflects the comprehensive approach of Islamic

principles to human incentives. It stresses the balance between self-

regarding and others-regarding interests, between for-profit and non-

profit activities, between competitive and cooperative relations.

Islamic rules draw clear and decisive boundaries between the two

domains, and successfully achieve internal balance and equilibrium

between the two. The obligation of zakat and prohibition of riba are

two clear examples. Capitalism stresses for-profit and market-oriented

approach for nearly all economic problems. Communism, on the

other hand, relies mainly on non-profit mechanisms to solve the same

problems. Islamic economics, in contrast, takes a balanced approach.

Both for-profit and non-profit mechanisms are essential for satisfying

economic needs.


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 93

        No economy can thrive solely on for-profit transactions. In

fact, the existence of the society, through families and communities, is

based on cooperative rather than for-profit bases. Nonprofit

organizations account for about 90% of all non-governmental schools

and colleges, and two-thirds of all hospitals in the U.S. (Hansmann,

1996).

        Accordingly, many financial and economic objectives can be

achieved through cooperative, rather than for-profit, arrangements.

The most obvious example is insurance. While commercial insurance

is widely considered unacceptable from Shar�cah point of view,

cooperative and mutual insurance is unanimously accepted.

Cooperative arrangements can be more efficient than commercial

instruments, and thus better able to serve relevant needs.

Interdependence

        It is important to note that cooperative arrangements differ

from donations and charity. Professor Stephen Covey (1990) classifies

human relations into three stages depending on their degree of

maturity:

    1. Dependence
    2. Independence
    3. Inter-dependence

The first stage is dependence, where one relies on others to satisfy his

or her needs. This is especially true in the early stages of life, where a

child is largely dependent on his parents and family. Afterwards, one


94 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

builds up his identity and tries to be independent from others. The

most advanced stage is inter-dependence. It is a mutual relationship

between independent persons that utilizes benefits of cooperation to

achieve results no single person can.

        These three stages have their counterparts in economic

behavior. Dependence corresponds to reliance on donations and

charities. The receiver is dependent on the donor. At any point in

time, there are always people who cannot satisfy their needs on their

own, and must depend on others for that. Independence corresponds

to self-interest, for-profit, transactions. Agents get what they want

through their own resources. The most advanced stage, inter-

dependence, corresponds to mutual and cooperative behavior. It is

also called reciprocal relations (e.g. Gintis et. al., 2005; Sobel, 2005).

These are neither pure for-profit nor pure charity, but combine

properties of both to achieve higher objectives. While communism was

concerned mainly with solving the problem of dependent agents,

capitalism is concerned mainly with achieving independence through

self-interest and market forces. Islamic economics acknowledges these

two types of relations, but adds to them the more mature relation:

cooperation and inter-dependence.

        As we shall see later, cooperative insurance is built on

reciprocal, inter-dependent relations, rather than pure charity and

donation.


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 95

Principle of Acceptability

        This principle belongs to methodology but logical sequencing

requires presenting it at this point. The principle states that all

economic dealing are generally acceptable unless otherwise stated by

Shar�cah (e.g. Ibn Taymiah [3]).

        The principle is based on the assumption that economic

interactions aim to satisfy normal human needs and preferences. Islam

views man to be driven by nature to the good, and thus normal

interactions will normally lead to the good of the society. Obviously,

evil exists, and this is why there are rules to govern economic

behavior.

        These rules are on the preventive side with respect to for-profit

activities, but are on the affirmative side with respect to non-profit

activities. The reason is the nature of human incentives. According to

al-Shatibi [11], whenever there are sufficient incentives to pursue

legitimate objectives, like seeking profits, the Qur’�n will not overly

insist on it to avoid extreme responses. On the other hand, when there

are less than sufficient incentives to pursue some objectives, like giving

donations, the Qur’�n will particularly emphasize it to compensate for

reduced incentives. This explains why most Shar�cah regulations of

for-profit transactions are on the preventive side. Nonetheless, the

Qur’�n in many verses praises commerce and trade (e.g. 73:20).

        The principle of acceptability is a corner stone for innovation.

There are no limits on human imagination and creativity, as long as it

does not cause more harm than good. One needs only to check that


96 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

none of the prohibited dealings contaminate the transaction. Beyond

that, all possibilities are open.

        Accordingly, if two views are presented regarding a certain

product, one considers it acceptable while the other doesn’t, then the

burden of proof is on the latter. Those who accept don’t have to prove

it, since this is the default position of Shar�cah.

Roots of Prohibited Dealings

        Based on the principle of acceptability, we need to worry

mainly about prohibited dealings with respect to for-profit activities.

Generally speaking, most regulations of for-profit activities serve to

prevent the most serious unjust dealings: Riba and gharar. We have

already discussed the concept of gharar in detail, so we will focus here

on riba , as well as the common aspects of the two.

         Riba or usury, is essentially interest on lending. Islam is not

unique to prohibit riba , since all divine religions do (Chapra, 2004).

The objective of finance in general is to promote growth and fair

distribution of real resources. Prosperity and welfare are determined

ultimately by real wealth. Accordingly, the financial sector works to

serve the real sector.

         Riba separates finance from real transactions. Since the two

counter-values of a loan are identical, it follows that interest becomes

purely the cost of time, or the cost of pure finance. Pure debt creation

is less constrained than real wealth creation; it takes only the

agreement of the two parties to postpone a due debt for additional

interest. Consequently, growth of debt tends to exceed that of the real


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 97

economy. With compounded interest, debt services grow much faster

than real income, and will take an increasingly dominant share of it.

For example, debt services in 2003 took more than 80% of exports of

Lebanon, 63% for Burundi, and in 2001 it was 82% for Sierra Leon

(World Bank, 2005). Thus the real sector will be servicing the financial

sector, instead of the other way around. The economy obviously

cannot normally continue to grow, since interest-based debt, if not

checked, threatens to absorb economic wealth through its unlimited

growing services.

        The devastating consequences of interest-based debt make it

necessary to regulate financing from the beginning to avoid

uncontrollable results. Islamic principles therefore make finance an

inseparable part of real activities. That is why there is no “pure

financing” instrument in Shar�cah. Islamic instruments have debt

finance as an integrated component of real transactions, as in deferred

sale and salam. As long as debt is integrated with real activities, there is

no issue in taking its costs into account. Such costs are controlled by

real transactions, and thus debt cannot grow on its own.

        This points to the difference between interest on lending and

mark-up in credit sale. Interest is a self-replicating mechanism that

makes debt grow and multiply independent of the real economy. As

mentioned above, this eventually drains real resources, obviously to

the benefit of lenders. Mark-up, on the other hand, is time value

integrated into the real transaction. This eliminates the possibility of

self-replication of debt. Time value as such is not the issue; rather it is

the growth of debt independent of real wealth that threatens social


98 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

welfare. By integrating time value with real transactions, this

replicating mechanism is eliminated.

        The difference between integrated and separated debt is very

much like the difference between a normal and a cancerous cell. A

cancerous cell grows and multiplies in a disorderly and uncontrollable

way. It escapes the control mechanism that keeps cells growing in their

normal and orderly way (Buckman, 1997, p. 9). When debt evades

control mechanisms, it grows on its own, just as cancerous cells do.

The control mechanism is what keeps cells synchronized and

integrated to perform normal body functions. Islamic regulations of

debt represent the necessary control mechanism that keeps debt

synchronized with the real economy. Interest makes debt evade

control, and thus become a threat to the economy.

Principle of Integration

        Both riba and gharar work to sever subjective preferences from

objective wealth. Riba applies to time, while gharar applies to risk.

Time and risk, as pointed out earlier, are in fact two sides of the same

coin. Separating one implies separating the other. It is not surprising

therefore that Shar�cah prohibits both.

        The separation of time and risk from real activities leads to

divergence of the financial sector from the real sector. However, the

separation is inconsistent with the nature of economic relations, and

thus is not sustainable. This makes it increasingly costly to keep the

two sectors apart. The rising costs of separation defeat its original

purpose, namely efficiency and reduced transaction costs. Eventually,


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 99

the real sector will pay much more for separation than it costs to keep

the two sectors integrated. Shar�cah, therefore, insists on the

integration between two sectors to achieve balanced and sustained

economic growth. This is an essential principle in developing Islamic

financial products.

Integration and Specialization

        Integration can be seen as a constraint on economic behavior,

but it is a productive constraint. As already pointed out by Elster

(2000), not all constraints are inefficient. North (1990) explains how

institutional constraints help reduce transaction and informational

costs. Specialization, which drives economic progress, as economists

recognized long time ago, is a sort of self-constraints to improve

productivity and discipline activities. Integration builds upon

specialization at the input level to synchronize the output of various

sectors. As Milgrom and Roberts (1992) point out, “specialization

requires coordination” (p. 25).

        Advocates of derivatives argue that separation of risk from

underlying assets makes it more efficient to manage risk, since it is a

form of specialization and division of labor. But risk is a purely mental

construct, as discussed earlier, and thus cannot actually exist outside

human mind. Separation of risk therefore is an abstraction from reality

rather than specialization. While specialization naturally imposes

greater discipline on economic behavior, abstraction by design lifts

most boundaries and constraints that arise from the complexity of

reality. Since abstraction is not sustainable, the real sector eventually


100 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

pays most of the costs of the undisciplined behavior resulting from

abstraction. It is therefore necessary to assure the integration of the

real and financial sectors from the beginning to avoid serious problems

of coordination failure.

Evaluation of Financial Products

        A direct implication of the principle of integration is that

money-for-money instruments are unacceptable if performed for

profit. An acceptable transaction therefore must incorporate a real

component, e.g. goods, utilities or services. Although the real

component is necessary for integration, it is not sufficient. In some

cases goods are used only for artificial integration. Legitimate

contracts involving real goods or services might be used in a manner

that defeats the purpose of integration; namely to create real value. It

is quite possible to combine acceptable contracts such that the final

result is unacceptable. This is called hila (artifice) or hiyal (artifices). In

                                      �                   �

artifices to circumvent usury, for example, real components are used

for the purpose of lending. Real goods therefore are used to obtain

financing, instead of financing used to facilitate real objectives.

        The problem of artifices arises from the tension between

substance and form of financial arrangements. Which side has the

precedence over the other and when, determines the solution. It is

useful to note, however, that this problem is not confined to Islamic

jurisprudence. We already noted that the same problem arose in the

late nineteenth century in the West with respect to futures and options.

It arises now with respect to over-the-counter derivatives, as well as


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 101

accounting rules pertaining to such derivatives. Manipulation in both

domains is common, as reflected in Enron and similar scandals (e.g.

Partnoy, 2003). The manipulation hinges on the tension between the

letter and the spirit of the law, between form and substance of the

financial product. What makes Islamic jurisprudence different,

however, is its moral dimension. The intention of evading the

commands of Allah (s.w.t) is considered a major sin, regardless of

whether or not it could be proven in court.

        There are theoretically two extremes with respect to the

relation between form and substance: to consider either form only, or

substance only, and ignore the other. Both are Islamically not

acceptable. As Ibn Taymiah [1] clearly shows, hiyal were unanimously

condemned by the companions of the Prophet, peace be upon him.

Ibn al-Qayyim [6] therefore reports that no prominent Muslim

scholar endorses all kinds of artifices. This implies that form or means

cannot have an absolute precedence over substance or ends. On the

other hand, all scholars agree that good intentions are not enough to

approve a certain transaction. This means that ends do not justify

means. Accordingly, neither of the two extremes is acceptable, nor in

fact practical.

        This implies that scholars generally agree that there must be a

balance or consistency between form and substance. Thus, differences

among scholars in this regard can be attributed to differences in

determining the degree of consistency, not regarding consistency in

principle. This leads to the next principle of Islamic financial

engineering:


102 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

Principle of Consistency

         This principle states that form and substance of Islamic

products must be consistent with each other; i.e. form should serve

substance, and means should conform to ends. This principle relies on

generally acceptable fiqh maxims, like “actions are based on

objectives,” and “meanings supersede litters” (e.g. Ibn al-Qayyim [6]).

Accordingly, evaluation of a product should go through the following

steps (Figure 10):

                            product          evaluation
                             design
                                    no       substance
                        revise
                                            acceptable?
                                                   yes
                                    no         form
                                            acceptable?
                                                   yes
                                              product
                                            acceptable
                 Figure 10: Process of Product Evaluation


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 103

    1. Evaluate the substance or the end result of the product. If
        acceptable, go to step 2. Otherwise, go to step 3.
    2. Evaluate the form of the product. If acceptable, the product is
        acceptable. Otherwise, go to step 3.
    3. Revise the product, and then go to step 1.

Note that we start with substance, and then move to form. Both are

necessary for final approval of the product. Neither one, however, is

sufficient alone for full approval.

        To give an example, consider two contemporary financial

products: murabaha and ceinah, including organized tawarruq. Both are

used for financing, but murabaha requires the financier (bank) to

purchase the good the customer requests, then sell it to the customer

for a profit on deferred-payment basis. In tawarruq, the financier sells to

the customer a good for a deferred price, then sells it again on the

customer’s behalf for cash, and deposits the money in the customer’s

account.

        In terms of substance, the objective of murabaha is to provide

the good the customer needs for a deferred price. The final result

therefore is a normal sale. The objective of tawarruq, on the other

hand, is to provide liquidity. The customer eventually gets cash in

exchange for a debt of a larger magnitude. It therefore ends in pure

debt financing. Obviously, in terms of substance, murabaha serves a

legitimate objective, but tawarruq serves simply the same objective of

riba. Not surprisingly, therefore, murabaha is widely accepted, while


104 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

organized tawarruq is highly controversial (the Fiqh Academy in Mecca

in fact rejected the latter in its ruling in 2003).

        Given that the objective of murabaha is legitimate, we have to

be sure it is implemented properly. The process must observe the

detailed Shar�cah rules, like avoiding selling of what you don’t have or

making profit without being liable to the underlying good. Once these

rules are observed, the instrument is acceptable since it passes through

both stages of evaluation. For tawarruq or ceinah, it will not help if all

detailed rules were observed, since the final result is not legitimate.

        A good example to further clarify this point is to compare pork

with lamb or beef. Pork is positively prohibited by the Qur’�n, no

matter how the pig was killed, whether slaughtered properly or not.

The means are not relevant if the end itself is prohibited. Lamb, in

contrast, is good in itself, so it has to be slaughtered properly to be

completely acceptable. Obviously, not all animals are sheep, nor all

are pigs. But it is certainly possible that people would differ whether a

certain animal is a pig or a sheep. This would be normally tolerated,

as it is only humane to differ. Thus, in many instances we can view

differences of scholars regarding some artifices as differences regarding

the type of “animal” rather than how it was processed.

Strategies for Product Development

        The next step in Islamic financial engineering is to examine

strategies and techniques for developing financial products. There are

generally three strategies, depending on the starting point of the

development process:


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 105

   1. To start from conventional products.
   2. To start from Islamic products.
   3. To start from the real needs of customers.

Imitation

        The first strategy is to have a conventional (but Islamically

questionable) product as a reference, and then use Islamic contracts to

construct an equivalent product with almost identical properties. The

strategy is also called “reverse engineering” (Iqbal, 1999). Examples

include:

   •    Replicating a conventional loan with interest through tawarruq
        or ceinah.
   •    Time deposits are replicated through reversed tawarruq.
   •    A financial call option is replicated through c urbun.
   •    Interest rate swap is replicated through reciprocal tawarruq and
        reversed tawarruq, with different markup structures, and so
        forth.

This strategy is probably the easiest for developing products, since the

target is already determined. This probably explains why it has been

used for centuries. Imitation might help particularly in early stages of

development of the Islamic industry, but its drawbacks could affect the

long term pace of the industry. The main drawbacks are:

        1. First, the strategy gives persistent precedence of form over

substance, and means over ends. Application of Islamic rules becomes


106 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

a matter of passive and visionless observance of Shar�cah with little

confidence in its economic value.

       2. The strategy makes the Islamic industry by design a follower

of the conventional industry. Since it is based on replication and

imitation, conventional industry will always be the leader. This

contradicts the essence of creativity and innovation, and thus the

strategy cannot belong to financial engineering in its true sense.

       3. Since imitation implies the same objective of conventional

instruments, but with the additional constraints of Shar�cah rulings, it

follows that Islamic instruments will always be inferior to conventional

ones. This is a well known result in optimization theory where a

binding constraint cannot improve the value of the objective function.

This inferiority arises because of taking the conventional product as

the objective function. The more natural approach is to take Shar�cah

rules as given constraints, then derive an objective function for which

the solution is optimal. That is, we should start from Shar�cah rules

then arrive at the objective function, rather than going in the opposite

direction.

       4. Conventional instruments are developed to solve the

problems of the conventional industry. Replicating these products will

make Islamic institutions susceptible to the same problems for which

these products were developed to solve. In other words, the strategy

will bring in new and alien problems to the industry. As these

problems get transmitted, the need for conventional products becomes

stronger. This in turn necessitates replicating more products, which


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 107

adds more problems, and so on. The circle becomes self-feeding and

the industry risks loosing its identity in the process.

        It should be noted that in a healthy competitive market,

imitation will lose its edge and its returns will diminish rapidly. The

strategy therefore is not sustainable.

Mutation

        The second strategy is to start from acceptable Islamic

products, and try different variations and modifications on them, and

see how the resulting products could be used. Using the jargon of

genetic algorithms (GA), existing products will be subjected to mutations

and cross-over, then using a selection criterion based on degree of

integration, for example, superior products are retained and poor ones

are dropped. The process is repeated until further improvements

become minimal. Genetic algorithms are used for a wide range of

applications, and can be effective in evolving desirable solutions for

which traditional techniques fail (see for example Mitchell, 1998;

Holland, 1995; and Goldberg, 1989).

        The strategy could generate effectively infinite number of

products. Given that the starting point is acceptable products, and

based on the principle of acceptability, a substantial part of evolved

products would be acceptable. This shows that the space of Islamic

products is very rich and open.

        This strategy deserves a full study on its own, but we will try to

apply it in a primitive, non-genetic form, in the next section.


108 VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING

Satisfaction

        The third strategy starts from actual needs of customers, then

go back and see which products or designs could serve these needs.

The strategy works in the opposite direction of the previous strategy,

and therefore the two complement each other.

        Choosing the real needs for developing products is the natural

process of market evolution. Customers to a large extent determine the

direction of the industry. Economic progress in fact can be measured

by the ability of agents to satisfy their needs. Products, whether

financial or physical, are means to satisfy such needs. This is another

example of how in reality ends determine means, not the other way

around.

        An example of this strategy applies to lending. Consider a

consumer who approaches the bank seeking a loan. He asks for cash

money. But this is not his actual need, since he must use this money in

another real transaction to satisfy his actual need. For example, he

might use it to purchase an appliance or renew his furniture. Thus the

real need is the final good, not the initial cash. For Islamic banks, this

means that the bank should finance the ultimate good needed by the

customer. If this is difficult for logistic reasons, advanced technology

could greatly eliminate these obstacles, meanwhile improves the

profitability of the bank.

        If the customer needs the money to pay an existing debt, the

same process could be applied to the creditor. The creditor, again,

must use the money for real purposes. The bank should be ready to

finance the creditor’s needs using the customer’s money. Money is a


VI. FINANCIAL ENGINEERING 109

veil, as Classical economists long time ago argued. This means that

real transactions are the ultimate objective of economic transactions.

With the advancement of technology and electronic money (e.g.

Shiller, 2003, pp. 73-75), we are approaching the “cashless society”

where money becomes a transparent layer revealing real transactions

behind. Not only this improves the integration of financial and real

sectors, it also makes financing more efficient with less transaction

costs, meanwhile closer to Shar�cah principles. Instead of taking cash

then using it for real transactions, the real transaction is directly

financed without the middle step. This shows that Islamic finance is

potentially more efficient than conventional finance (see al-Jarhi,

2002). In other words, financing real transactions of customers is the

ultimate alternative for lending and tawarruq products alike.

Conclusion

        This section outlined some principles and strategies of Islamic

financial engineering. The argument is that credible Islamic

instruments are likely to be more efficient than conventional ones. The

Islamic industry however needs to review applied strategies for

product development to take full advantage of such efficiency. The

following section attempts to apply the above framework for

developing hedging strategies for Islamic instruments.


                                 VII
                 ISLAMIC INSTRUMENTS FOR HEDGING

The term “hedging” is commonly used to mean minimizing exposure

to risk. Although “hedging” differs from “insurance” (e.g. Bodie and

Merton, 1998, pp. 224-225), we will take the term in its broad

meaning. Risk, in any case, cannot be eliminated from economic

activities. It is now a common view that financial intermediation is

about managing risk, rather than avoiding risk (e.g. Heffernan, 1996,

p. 163). And investors are well aware of the first rule of the game:

“nothing ventured, nothing gained” (Bernstein, 1996, p. 256). Thus

hedging effectively means managing risk, rather than eliminating it.

        As discussed earlier, the challenge is to use hedging

instruments that can achieve the benefits of risk distribution but do not

lend themselves to gambling. That is, these instruments shall be

integrated with real, value-adding activities, and may not be “neutral”

with respect to gambling.

        There is more than one approach to hedging. Three possible

strategies are outlined:

        1. Economic hedging
        2. Cooperative hedging
        3. Contractual hedging


112 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

Economic Hedging

         This strategy stems from the decision maker and needs no

explicit arrangements with other agents to achieve desired hedging.

The most obvious and oldest example is to diversify investments.

According to Bernstein (1996): “Investors diversify their investments,

because diversification is their best weapon against variance of return”

(p. 252). Diversification is an essential hedging strategy that stands

alone as well as complements other strategies.

         It   might   appear however that       diversification   hinders

specialization. By definition, specialization requires concentration and

focus of capital and labor. To the extent that the two strategies

interfere with each other, it is a trade off decision. However,

specialization can compensate for diversification through integrating

the output with complementary products to minimize risk of loss

(Ashkenas et. al., 2002, p. 7). In other words, integration at the output

level may compensate for loss of diversification at the input level.

Further, investors in a company specializing in a certain market can

diversify its risks through holding a portfolio of diversified shares.

Investors therefore are better able to diversify risks than companies, as

Milgrom and Roberts (1992) point out. Thus, specialization at the firm

level can be compensated through diversification at investors level

(op.cit., p. 587).

Alignment of Assets and Liabilities

         An important source of risk is the asymmetry between

revenues and costs, or assets and liabilities. This asymmetry exposes


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 113

the business to liquidity risks when due payments on the liabilities side

are mismatched with those on the assets side. Further, firms are

exposed to market risks when production is not well aligned with

demand, causing risks of loss due to quick price changes and demand

shifts.

         Real business firms are continuously seeking technologies and

strategies to align their revenues and costs. The Japanese “just-in-

time” production, “direct-to-customer” sales strategy of Dell

Computers, and efficient supply systems of Wal-Mart, all are examples

(Evans and Wurster, 2000). Firms are networking with their suppliers

and customers to create “virtual integration” of the supply chain,

making it more flexible and responsive to market changes with less

frictions and minimum costs (Kelley, 1994, pp. 187-189; Ashkenas et.

al., 2002).

         Financial firms, in contrast, tend to have persistent

misalignments between their assets and liabilities. Borrowing short and

lending long is the core business of banks. Insurance companies

likewise have imbalanced sheet structure, with huge contingent

liabilities and minor certain assets. Although it opens some profit

opportunities, mismatching creates dangerous risks to the industry as

well as the economy. The creation of central banks and deposit

insurance, although attenuated systemic consequences, contributed to

the persistence of the problem.

         Derivatives play an important role in shifting some of the risks

of misaligned balance sheets, and this might help explain their

increasing growth. As these risks are transferred to other players, firms


114 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

find it more profitable to further misalign their balance sheets, leading

to additional use of derivatives, an so on.

       From an Islamic point of view, it is well known that Islamic

banks are supposed to enjoy much more symmetric and aligned

balance sheets, and thus much more stable structure (Khan and

Mirakhor, 1987). That is, alignment of the balance sheet appears as an

essential property of the Islamic system. The use of derivatives by

Islamic institutions therefore is inconsistent with the nature of their

structure, and would make them experience the same problems of the

conventional industry, as pointed out in the last section.

Natural Hedge

       Aligning assets and liabilities to reduce interest rate or currency

risks is called “natural hedge” (Steinherr, 2000, pp. 29, 289). The

exposure to a risk factor thus is offset by an opposite exposure to that

factor (riskinstitute.ch; 3.2006). Balance sheet hedge is done by altering

asset and/or liability repricing characteristics or volumes to reduce the

firm’s interest rate risk exposure without purchasing derivative

instruments like interest rate swaps or futures (americanbanker.com;

3.2006). An exporter with a USD liability may use an expected USD

income stream from future exports to hedge the currency risk

associated with the USD liability (stats.govt.nz; 3.2006). Companies

use natural hedging to avoid costs of derivatives hedging. According to

Goldman Sachs, hedging $500 million worth of earnings cost $26

million (Sparks, 2000). Many companies instead revert to natural

hedging to avoid currency risks.


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 115

        Heffernan (1996) provides another example of reducing risks

through matching assets and liabilities. A global bank working with

multiple currencies can reduce its currency risk through

“multicurrency-based share capital;” that is, to denominate its share

capital in multiple currencies. An example is the Scandinavian Bank

Group, which reconstituted its Sterling capital in four currencies: US

Dollar, Swiss Franc, Deutsche Mark, and Sterling. If share capital is

denominated in a mixture of currencies to match the volume of

business assets and liabilities, then capital ratios will not change by

much during exchange rate fluctuations. Accordingly, “currency risk is

reduced without using hedging instruments” (p. 194).

Dynamic Hedging

        Dynamic hedging refers to trading strategies that can replicate

the payoff of a given derivative using only the underlying security.

Assuming complete markets and frictionless world, an investor may be

able to find a portfolio that pays the same payoff as the derivative pays

at maturity without any payment except the initial investment. The

portfolio is called a replicating portfolio, and the derivative must worth

the same as the replicating portfolio. If it is not, then there is an

arbitrage opportunity (Slutz, 2004). This is also called “delta-hedging.”

According to MIT Laboratory for Financial Engineering, “delta-

hedging strategies are recipes for replicating the payoff of a complex

security by sophisticated dynamic trading of simpler securities”

(lfe.mit.edu; 12.2005).


116 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

         This strategy is used for pricing derivatives, as was pioneered

by Merton (1973) for option pricing. However, perfect replication is

impossible with incomplete markets and transaction costs. Bertsimas

et. al. (2001) solve for the problem of optimal replication in incomplete

markets. They use stochastic dynamic programming to construct a

self-financing dynamic portfolio strategy involving only the

fundamental securities that most closely approximate the payoff of the

derivative based on mean-square error.

         This means that dynamic strategies can be used to replicate

derivatives without actually buying any. Synthetic derivatives (e.g.

synthetic options) can be constructed instead of actually buying

options. Although they are not perfect substitutes, the approximation

can be close enough to satisfy the needs of investors who prefer not to

deal with derivatives. Many writers, however, have pointed to possible

instabilities that dynamic hedging might cause to markets (e.g.

Steinherr, 2000). This should be taken into account in evaluating such

strategies.

Cooperative Hedging

         Cooperative behavior is not residual to economic life. It forms

an essential framework for social interactions, as discussed in the

previous section. Accordingly, many important economic problems

can be effectively solved through cooperation rather than for-profit

arrangements, particularly problems of risk sharing and distribution.

According to Shiller (2003, p. 93), reciprocity is necessary for risk


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 117

sharing and management, particularly when such behavioral concept

is lacking today.

        Although commercial insurance is widely adopted, mutual

insurance is also common. About half of life insurance policies in the

U.S. are issued by mutual insurance (Hansmann, 1996). Cooperative

insurance enjoys the risk sharing and distribution of commercial

insurance, but can reduce problems of moral hazard and conflict of

interests that accompany it. Further, available evidence indicates that

mutual structure might be more stable than stock-ownership

structures. According to Gowland (1994), 60% of shareholder-owned

saving & loans thrifts were facing imminent failure during the S&L

debacle in late eighties, while only 25% of mutually owned were in the

same category (Heffernan, 1996, p. 294).

        From an Islamic point of view, commercial insurance is a

gharar contract, and thus is not acceptable. Cooperative insurance, in

contrast, is a non-profit arrangement, and thus can be accepted

despite the large uncertainties involved. The main difference between

the two, from an Islamic point of view, is the liability of the insurance

company. A commercial (stock-owned) insurance company is

obligated to pay the claims regardless of the size of available funds

from subscriptions. Cooperative insurance on the other hand is limited

by the size of available funds: If funds are not sufficient then either

policy holders would voluntarily contribute the deficit, or the

compensation will be reduced in proportion to available funds (al-

Dharir [12], p. 641; al-Suwailem [9]). This not-for-profit and limited-

liability structure enhances incentives to monitor and discipline


118 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

members to avoid exploiting the system, and thus problems of moral

hazard are also reduced. Further, since derivatives’ main drawback is

the unproductive speculation they invite in, mutual hedging eliminates

speculation by excluding profits. It becomes an arrangement between

hedgers only, not between hedgers and speculators, as derivatives are.

This brings in the benefits of risk distribution without creating

additional risks that drain real resources and endanger the stability of

the system.

         Through     cooperative     arrangements,   therefore,    Muslim

investors and Islamic institutions can join to share risks they are facing.

Since it is not-for-profit, the arrangements are quite flexible and can

accommodate any type of risk.

Cooperative Hedging for Currency Risks

         Cooperative hedging is an effective strategy for currency risks

for a simple reason: Shar�cah imposes strong restrictions on currency

for-profit trading that makes conventional hedging nearly impossible.

Accordingly, the most suitable risk management strategy for currency

risks is through cooperative, not-for-profit techniques.

         One way to do so is for Islamic institutions to establish a

cooperative fund to distribute and share currency risks. Members who

own this fund must have different risk profiles in order to diversify

their risks efficiently. Each member will perform his operations

normally, but would credit any gains or losses of currency exchange to

his account with the fund. Surpluses are kept as reserves to cover

future deficits. Initial deficits are covered from initial capital provided


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 119

by members. To the extent that members’ risks are uncorrelated, gains

and losses will be canceled out, and members will be able to hedge

their currency risks. Detailed structure of the fund could be designed

according to members’ preferences, but the basic property is being a

cooperative structure; i.e. all risks of the fund are ultimately borne by

members. This achieves risk sharing in its purist form, without the

negative consequences of speculative trading. Other non-cooperative

techniques for hedging currency risks are presented later in this

section.

Bilateral Mutual Adjustment

        Since cooperative structures are not for-profit, there is no

minimum of the number of members involved. Although a large

number of participants would help diversify the risks, the absence of

such condition makes it very flexible in cases where not many agents

might be involved in.

        This feature can be used to design bilateral risk sharing

between the financier and the customer in ordinary Islamic finance.

Consider a customer who purchases an asset through a long-term

arrangement. The financier faces risks of changing rates of return, and

would like to hedge against it. If it is a lease contract, the two parties

may agree to renew the contract by mutual consent periodically (say

bi-annually), where the new rent will reflect prevailing prices. But

suppose it was a murabaha, where the price is debt and therefore

cannot be increased. How can the two parties arrange a bilateral

hedge?


120 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

        One way to handle it is as follows. If the rate of return rises, the

customer would pay a higher installment, in exchange for reducing his

balance accordingly. That is, by paying a higher installment the

customer is speeding up the payment of his debt, and thus shortening

the duration of the contract. For the financier, he is getting more cash

and thus can utilize it at the higher rate of return. If the rate of return

declines, the customer would pay lower installments but with a longer

period of payment. The financier gives up some of the liquidity, but

secures predictable future payments. In any case total debt is fixed and

does not increase in any manner. What changes is the amount of the

installment and, consequently, the maturity date. In other words,

variability of the rate of return is reflected in variability of the duration

of the contract. No additional payments beyond those specified in the

contract are made. Since this change is made with mutual consent at

the time the rate changes, no disputable uncertainty exists in the contract.

No party gets something for nothing. Higher installments provide

liquidity to the financier but reduce the duration of the payment.

Lower installments provide liquidity to the customer but extend the

duration of the payment. The arrangement therefore balances rights

and obligations of each party in a cooperative manner.

Contractual Hedging

        This strategy focuses on contractual, for-profit, instruments. As

discussed before, risk management for-profit tools in Islamic finance

are inseparable from real activities. Thus a single instrument would

provide finance, risk management as well as ownership together. We


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 121

shall review the main Islamic instruments and see how can they be

modified to accommodate risk distribution. The approach taken here

is based on strategies of mutation and satisfaction discussed in the

previous section.

Mudarabah
        The most ancient form of business financing is mudarabah,

where the capital owner (rab-ul- mal ) provides capital and the agent

(mudarib) would utilize it in business projects. Profits then are shared

based on predetermined ratios. There are mainly three types of risks

involved. These are:

    1. Risk of misreporting
    2. Risk of loss
    3. Risk of liquidity

Since mudarabah represents a real investment, there is no significant

liquidity risk from Shar�cah point of view.

Misreporting Risk

        This is the most common risk related to mudarabah , where the

agent might announce losses, when in fact the project is making profit.

By misreporting the agent would keep the entire profits to himself.

According to a survey by Khalil et. al. (2002), misreporting is the

prime reason Islamic banks are not applying mudarabah on the asset

side of their balance sheets.


122 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

       Although mudarabah is a sharing arrangement, nothing could

prevent banks from due diligence and careful examination of

companies requesting finance. In fact, the current practice of

conventional lending requires banks to extensively study the balance

sheet and income statement of loan applicants, in addition to

management and ownership. The bank will not provide the loan

unless it is sufficiently confident the borrower is able to pay back from

its own generated revenues. Banks therefore are only one step away

from sharing the borrower’s income. Islamic banks should apply the

same level of due diligence for applicants of mudarabah, or even

higher, since they are exposed to downside risk. This means that, in

equilibrium, Islamic banks would finance better businesses, and

achieve higher success rate, than those financed through debt (al-

Suwailem, 2005b).

       In some cases, however, it is the customer who might refuse

sharing financing, since he prefers to keep all the upside to himself and

not share it with the bank. This should not be an obstacle, since the

two parties can agree to share profits on a regressive scale, i.e. rates

that decline with increasing profits. This may satisfy the customer

preferences without sacrificing the benefits of sharing.

Credit-based Mudarabah

       For small businesses or single deals, the bank can apply what

might be roughly described as “credit-based mudarabah. ” That is, the

bank will not provide capital except after the transaction or the deal is

closed. This is based on the Hanbali view that mudarabah essentially is

                               �                      �


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 123

a labor contract, and thus capital or money needs not be paid upfront.

It becomes effectively a form of wujuh partnership, also accepted by

the Hanbali as well as the Hanafi schools (Ibn Qudamah [5]).

      �                          �

Accordingly, the bank would sign a mudarabah agreement with the

customer, have him arrange the deal with related parties, then share

realized profits. For example, the agent or mudarib would purchase

material on short-term credit basis with the right to cancel in 48 hours,

say. Then he sells the material to the purchaser for a profit. The agent

then would present receipts of purchase and sale to the bank, upon

which the bank would pay the seller, receive the purchase price from

the purchaser, then pay the agent’s share in profits as agreed. If the

last deal for any reason is canceled, the first could be canceled also. In

this manner the bank pays only if the deal is closed, and thus risks of

failure and misreporting are brought to minimum.

Capital Risk

        In mudarabah, as well as most forms of partnership or
musharakah, investors face downside risk, i.e. risk of losing their capital.

Due diligence and conditional payment can greatly minimize these

risks, as discussed above. Other alternatives may also be useful.

        One alternative is to combine a deferred sale with partnership.

For example, the financier, instead of providing money to the

company, would sell required inputs, say, in return for a deferred price

plus a defined share of the company’s assets. This allows the financier

to hedge the downside meanwhile share in the upside.


124 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

        To see the logic of this combination, recall that in a deferred

sale the seller charges a fixed markup for deferring the payment. If the

seller is allowed to secure a fixed and determined profit through the

markup, then having the profit conditioned on the performance of the

purchaser seems more acceptable, since it makes the seller partly

shares the risks the purchaser faces.

        Note that this formula is equivalent to a deferred sale with

variable return. The variable return, however, is not linked to LIBOR

or a similar interest rate reference. Rather, it is linked to actual profits

of the customer. This relieves the customer from interest burden, and

at the same time allows the bank to enjoy better returns. There is no

conflict of interest between the two, since the bank gets higher returns

only if the customer does. More on this point later.

Third Party Hedging

        Another way to hedge the downside risk is through a third

party. This works as follows. The investor or financier provides money

to the company through partnership or musharakah, by which the

financier becomes a (passive) shareholder in the company. The

investor subsequently can sell all or part of his share to a third party.

For example, the investor may sell a portion, say 95%, of his share for

a deferred price that is equal to his capital, and keeps the remaining

5%. The remaining share allows the investor to participate in the

company’s profits, while the deferred price protects his investment.

        The third party (say an Islamic insurance company) enjoys the

participation in the company without advanced payment, and with


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 125

relatively low markup cost. What is more important is that the

company doesn’t bear any burden of debt at all. From the company’s

point of view, the investment is still a form of musharakah. Thus the

arrangement allows all parties to gain.

Deferred-price Sale

       Sale with deferred price, or bayc �jil, is very common in Islamic

finance. The main risks of deferred sale are:

    1. Credit risk
    2. Liquidity risk
    3. Rate of return risk

Credit risk can be treated mostly the same way conventional credit risk

is. The bank can take collaterals and guarantees to protect its

investment. For late or delayed payment, it wouldn’t help much to

charge the customer and add to his outstanding debt. The reason is

simple: If the customer is not able or not willing to pay, say, 1000, he

will be even less inclined to pay 1200. Charges will give the customer

fewer incentives to repay. The direct solution, applied successfully in

some well known Islamic banks, is to have direct access to the

customer’s income. The bank therefore will be able to deduct the

amount due directly on time. The delinquency rate of on such bank is

less than 0.3%, or 3 in 1000, without late charge fees of any kind.


126 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

Liquidity Risk

        Since the deferred price is a monetary debt, it is not acceptable

from Shar�cah point of view to sell it for cash. This means that, for

long-term debts, the bank might face liquidity risks, i.e. may not be

able to liquidate these debts or securitize them. There are at least two

solutions to this problem. One is to exchange debt for commodities

instead of cash. That is, the bank may use existing debt to pay for

assets or commodities the bank want to finance through murabaha.

The debt will be discounted appropriately, but this raises no

difficulties. Exchanging debt for commodity (dayn bi cayn) is acceptable

according to the M�liki school as well as Ibn Taymiah (al-Dharir [12]).

        The second solution is to combine monetary debt with real

assets into one portfolio, with debts not exceeding 50%, and then

securitize the portfolio. Contemporary scholars view this as acceptable

since the majority of the portfolio consists of real assets that can be

traded for cash. Additional solutions are discussed below.

Rate of Return Risk

        As pointed out earlier, since the deferred price is debt, it

cannot be increased after the sale is concluded. This means that to

have a floating rate on a deferred sale is incompatible with Shar�cah

maxims. For long-term debt, this exposes both parties to risk of

changing rate of return or markup rate. Since this is a legitimate need,

we are confident that there exist solutions that successfully meet

Shar�cah requirements.


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 127

        We have already pointed to one cooperative solution.

Variability of rate of return can be reflected in variability of duration

of the contract through changing the installment amount. If market

rate rises, the two parties mutually agree to raise the installment

amount, and thus shorten the duration. Conversely, if the market rate

declines, the two agree to reduce the installment and consequently

extend the duration. Although this does not change the explicit return

on the debt, it provides liquidity to the affected party, which can

compensate for lost return. This solution is cooperative since the

adjustment has to be made with mutual consent at the time of change.

This shall not pose a problem, however, since no party gets something

for nothing, as discussed before. Thus, the arrangement is incentive-

compatible and therefore it is time-consistent. This makes it in the

interest of the two parties ex post to agree on the change.

Diversified Deferred Price

        A more general solution is a diversified deferred price (al-

Suwailem, 2005a). Consider a murabaha to a corporate or sovereign

entity with payment duration of, say, 20 years, and annual rate of

5.2%. This means that the markup equals 51% of the total payment,

while the principal represents 49%. Instead of having the entire debt

in monetary terms, the mark up could up be in any agreed upon real

asset. It could be a defined amount of commodities, shares, fund

units, sukuk, or any mix of these. This structure provides the following

benefits to the financier:


128 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

        First, the deferred price is liquid, since 51% of it is in real

assets, and thus can be traded for cash. Hence it can be securitized or

issued in form of sukuk.

        Second, prices of the real assets allow the financier indirectly to

get returns linked to the market. Higher market returns will be

reflected in higher prices, and vice versa. This might be more valuable

than a floating rate, since the floating rate cannot compensate

deterioration in the price currency. For example, based on the US

Dollar index of New York Board of Trade, the Dollar lost about 20%

of its value since September 11, 2001. Further, the DJ commodity

index for example has appreciated in the same period by more than

60% (Figure 11). A floating rate on a Dollar-denominated debt would

have not recovered this lost value, especially with declining interest

rates on the Dollar. With diversified debt, much of the lost value could

have been recovered.

        For the debtor, the diversified price would relieve his debt

obligations if the real component closely matches his sources of

revenues. For example, an oil company or oil-exporting country might

choose oil as the main markup asset. A more diversified entity might

choose a more diversified basket of commodities. This means that the

debtor faces less risk than if the markup was predetermined, or was

linked to rates independent of his revenues.

        In fact, the choice of real assets instead of floating interest rates

could help both parties for a macroeconomic reason. It is well known

that interest rate and economic output are negatively correlated. Thus


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 129

            Figure 11: USD Index and DJ Commodities Index
                     Source: nybot.com and djindexes.com

a rise in interest rate implies lower economic performance, and vise

versa. An interest-linked debt therefore will generate higher returns to

the creditor exactly when economic conditions are unfavorable to the

borrower. Conversely, when the borrower is making good returns

because of an economic boom, the lender is getting low returns

because of low interest. This conflict of interest is absent if the price is

diversified through real assets.

Commodity-linked Bonds

       The diversified structure is somewhat close to “commodity-

linked bonds.” These bonds are structured so that their coupon

and/or principal payments are determined by the price of some

commodity (Dodd, 2005). Among the early references to the idea are


130 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

Lessard (1986) and Besley and Powell (1989). The idea has been

implement in late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries

(Borensztein et. al., 2004). According to researchers at the IMF,

commodity-linked bonds if issued by governments serve to prevent or

reduce debt crisis, promote international risk sharing, and facilitate

adjustment of fiscal variables to domestic economic conditions

(Borensztein et. al., 2004). Atta-Mensah (2004) from Bank of Canada

argues that commodity-linked bonds provide commodity-producing

countries an opportunity to hedge against fluctuations in their export

earnings.

       Commodity-linked bonds differ from diversified price sukuk in

that bonds pay money in exchange for money, while a diversified price

pays in kind and money in exchange for a good. Yet both instruments

work to relieve the borrower from interest burden, and thus provide

risk-sharing features. A related instrument is salam, which will be

discussed shortly.

Currency Risk in Murabaha

       Currency risk can be part of capital risk, and diversification

shall provide an indirect hedge against currency fluctuations.

Alternatively, one simple way to hedge currency risk in murabaha is to

have it transferred to the counterparty. If the counterparty is a

conventional entity, it may resort to conventional instruments. For

example, if an Islamic bank provides murabaha to a customer in Euro,

but capital is in USD, the customer (debtor) shall pay in USD instead

of Euro. The customer obviously may not take that risk, so it might


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 131

arrange a forward with its own bank, such that the conventional bank

issues a payment guarantee to the Islamic bank in USD. Costs of such

arrangements can be included in the overall pricing of the deal. If the

customer is an Islamic entity that may not use forwards, then the deal

can be done through “parallel murabaha ”: the Islamic bank sells to the

customer’s bank in USD, which in turn sells to the customer in Euro.

This intermediate murabaha can be performed by a conventional as

well as an Islamic entity, as long as it is willing to take the risk. The

point is that currency risks can be hedged within the murabaha

transaction, not separately. This is consistent with the overall

approach to integrate risk management with real activities, as

discussed earlier. This allows for risk management to be part of value-

adding transactions, which allows for hedging meanwhile curbs

speculation.

Value-based Salam

       Salam has been known much before the time of the Prophet,

peace be upon him. The advancement of payment in exchange for a

specified quantity of a defined good provides financing to the seller as

well as price discount to the buyer. The main problem with salam is the

price value of the good at maturity. This price might be much

different from the expected price, and the gap might wipe out the

benefits of the advanced payment. Price fluctuations were an

instrumental factor behind the emergence of futures markets. From an

Islamic point of view, futures are inconsistent with Shar�cah maxims,

and thus cannot be an adequate solution to the problem.


132 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

        There are many ways to address price fluctuations, but one

solution deserves careful analysis. It is called “value-based salam” (al-

Suwailem, 2005a). It works as follows. The buyer pays in advance the

full price, say 10,000, in exchange for oil, for example. Traditionally,

the quantity of the oil shall be determined upfront, i.e. number of

barrels to be delivered at maturity. In value-based salam, the value

rather than the quantity shall be determined upfront. Value is defined

as quantity times unit price, or number of barrels times barrel’s price.

Let the value agreed upon is 11,000. This means that the buyer pays

10,000 for an amount of oil the value of which at maturity is 11,000.

At maturity, the barrel’s price is determined from the market, and thus

the quantity becomes also determined (by dividing the value by the

barrel’s price). So if the barrel’s price at maturity is, say, 50, then the

quantity of oil to be delivered is 220 barrels.

        This form of salam has been approved by Ibn Taymiah, and his

opinion was cited by Ibn Muflih, a prominent Hanbali scholar,

                                      �                   �

without objection (al-Rajhi [13]). The buyer in this arrangement is

able to hedge against price fluctuations of the future good. If the price

at maturity declines, quantity to be delivered will rise to compensate

for the price reduction. If the price rises, the quantity declines. Thus

price fluctuations are internalized through the value determined at the

outset.

Discussion

        Value-based salam, however, may be questioned on Shar�cah

grounds, for two reasons:


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 133

       1. It violates the classical conditions of salam, whereby the
           quantity of the good must be specified upfront.
       2. It is essentially money for money, which makes it an
           indirect form of riba.

These two objections can be answered as follows:

    1. The condition on the quantity to be known aims at eliminating
       the possibility of dispute. Once dispute is absent, the condition
       needs not be observed for its own sake. If the value is
       determined, no possibility of dispute arises, since all variables
       will be determined from the market.
    2. The formula is not riba , neither in form nor in substance. The
       net result of the transaction is money for goods, not money for
       money. The buyer at maturity receives goods not money. The
       fact that the value of these goods is pre-arranged doesn’t make
       it objectionable. Not any more than murabaha, where the bank
       buys spot and sells deferred for a markup. Here the bank buys
       deferred and sells spot. So the two arrangements, murabaha
       and value-based salam, are essentially equivalent. The only
       difference is the sequence of steps.
    3. It should be noted that value-based salam provides an
       opportunity for the two parties to gain from the transaction.
       To see this, suppose the seller in the previous example is an oil
       company. Although the market price at maturity is 50, the
       company most likely is able to obtain the oil at a lower price,
       either through long-term relations in the industry or through


134 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

      its own reserves. So if it costs the company, say, 30 per barrel,
      this means that total actual cost for the company is 6,600, which
      is less than the total price it received. That is, the company is
      able to save 3,400, while the buyer is able to make 1,000. Both
      parties therefore win. This could not happen in a pure loan,
      since the two sides of the loan are identical by design. Here the
      two sides are different, and this difference allows the two
      parties to gain.
   4. Value-based salam differs from artifices of riba , like tawarruq
      and ceinah, in an important dimension. In these artifices, the
      same commodity could be used successively, by the same agent
      or by others, to generate additional debts without limit. There
      exists no upper bound on how many times the commodity is
      sold for deferred price then resold for cash. A single
      commodity therefore could in a very short period generate
      huge debts, as it is actually observed. In salam, including value-
      based salam, this is impossible, since the moment the
      commodity is delivered debt is extinguished. That is, at any
      given point in time, a single commodity cannot generate debt
      that exceeds its value plus the markup. The instrument self-
      regulates the amount of generated debt and internally imposes
      an upper bound on its possible size. This is consistent with the
      nature of Islamic finance in the absence of artifices, since all
      debts are used to finance real transactions. Consequently,
      possible debt size is bounded by real activities. This is in


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 135

        contrast to interest-based economy, where debt can grow
        indefinitely, irrespective of the size of the real economy.

Liquidity of Salam

        Value-based salam could neutralize the price risk. But what

about liquidity risk, especially for long-term contracts? The majority of

scholars argue that salam cannot be traded because it is a form of sale

before possession. The M�liki school accepts trading salam debt as long

as the sold good is not food or other essential commodity. Ibn

Taymiah accepts trading salam for a price not greater than the initial

price, to avoid making profits without assuming liability.

        However, parallel salam can be used as an alternative. The

buyer may sell a new salam contract with the same characteristics of

the original one. The difference is that he is now liable for the new

salam. If the original seller fails to deliver, the buyer (new seller) has to

deliver. The liability of salam traders in this structure is similar to that

of negotiable instruments. The law requires traders of these

instruments to be liable if the originator did not perform, unless it is

stated to be “without recourse” (e.g. West’s Encyclopedia, 1998). This

shouldn’t be a problem if the creditworthiness of the original seller was

sound. With large number of traders trading small fractions of the

good, the risk becomes reasonably tolerated.


136 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

Rate of Return Risk

       Value-based salam may allow for capital protection, as
murabaha does, but it does not allow for market-linked, variable return.

To allow for this option, we need to adopt a similar structure to that of

diversified murabaha . The deferred good now consists of two

components:

   1. Value-based component to minimize capital losses.
   2. Quantity-based component to allow for market return.

That is, the classical form of salam is useful in exposing investors to

market return. However, the downside is hedged through the value-

based form. This “hybrid salam” therefore manages both capital risk as

well as return risk. Liquidity risk is managed through parallel salam.

Other Applications of Value-based Salam

       Value-based salam has been suggested as a suitable instrument

for equity issuance. In corporate finance, there are theories of how

firms decide on their capital structure in terms of equity or debt. One

widely accepted theory, “picking order theory,” is built on the

assumption of informational asymmetry between managers and

outside investors. If outside investors are less informed than inside

managers, then issuing equity might send a bad signal about the firm.

Investors suspect that the firm’s existing assets are overvalued and thus

managers are trying to exploit this by issuing new equity with

overvalued price. Accordingly, issuing equity puts downward pressure

on share prices. To avoid negative signals of overvalued assets, Stewart


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 137

Myers (2001), professor of finance at MIT, suggests that firms issue

“deferred equity” based on value (p. 95). If inside information is likely

to be revealed in, say, one-year time, then the firm can issue an

unspecified number of equities for a fixed price of, say, $1000, such

that a year later investors get a number of shares equal $1000 divided

by the share price prevailing at that time. This instrument avoids the

informational problems of issuing equity since no specific valuation is

given to equity at time of issuance, and by the time of maturity inside

information could be revealed. This shows that value-based salam has

intrinsic economic value and not merely an artifice for pure financing.

       The instrument can also be used to create a “local currency.”

According to Gates (1998, pp. 155-156), in 1990 some communities in

the US issued a local “dollars” redeemable in food. That is, the local

dollars are issued in exchange for a specific number of US dollars, and

can be redeemed six months later, say, for food with same value.

These local dollars then started to circulate given the confidence in the

issuer. This helped the community overcome the problem of limited

sources of financing by creating their own “currency.” Again, this

shows the richness of value-based salam and its wide range of

applicability.

Payoff Structure of Contractual Hedging

       The above instruments have in common a payoff structure

similar to that of mixed-sum games. They allow for win-win outcomes,

but also imply the possibility of a zero-sum, win-lose, outcome. For

example, in value-based salam and diversified murabaha, the debtor


138 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

might not be able to obtain the commodities at reasonable costs.

Similarly, when combining deferred sale with sharing the debtor might

fail to generate profits and thus becomes a loser. As already discussed,

mixed games are acceptable as long as the positive outcome is the

objective of the game.

        This structure combines risk transfer with mutual gain, while

derivatives in contrast perform pure risk transfer with no room for

mutual gain. This means that Islamic instruments provide the benefits

of risk transfer without the costs of conflict of interests and relative

behavior. Further, derivatives shift risks to those who are more willing

to bear them, but not necessarily those who are better able to manage

them. Islamic instruments, in contrast, are likely to shift risks to those

more willing and more able to bear them. This follows from the

objective of the game which is mutual gain, whereby the two parties

seek to create value not merely to trade risk. Accordingly, risk is likely

to be transferred to those who are better able to contribute to value-

creation, not merely to bear risk. This implies better ability to manage

such risks in a more productive manner.

Specialized Institutions for Risk Management

        The above discussion also points to the need for specialized

Islamic institutions for managing risk. Third party hedging, for

example, requires such an entity. Mutual hedging of currencies and

other risks is another. The entity performing intermediate murabaha

for currency hedging is a third example. While Islamic insurance


VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS 139

companies represent a step in that direction, the traditional insurance

business falls short of comprehensive investment risk management.

       We have argued earlier that risk shall be integrated with real

transactions, and this might appear inconsistent with the call for

specialized institutions. There is no contradiction in fact between the

two, since such institutions would still manage risk in an integrated

approach, as suggested in third party hedging. Further, mutual

hedging requires devoted institutions for managing such mutual

arrangements. Thus, the need for specialized institutions arise from

the general need for professional Islamic risk management, be it based

on for-profit or non-profit techniques.

Summary

       Table 2 summarizes suggested Islamic instruments for hedging.

Other examples are provided in al-Suwailem [10]. Overall, there is no

limit on risk management tools based on Shar�cah standards. The

general principle of mutual gain and win-win payoff structure is

sufficient to generate a variety of instruments that allow for risk

transfer without conflict of interest and systemic instability. The above

examples point to how the strategy works; otherwise, each instrument

deserves independent research whereby detailed structure and

conditions are laid down in order to satisfy the specific needs of

Islamic institutions.


140 VII. HEDGING INSTRUMENTS

           Table 2: Islamic Hedging Instruments
   No Instrument                     Risks Hedged
   1  Asset-liability alignment      General
   2  Delta-hedging                  General
   3  Mutual hedging                 General
   4  Natural hedge                  Currency, rate of return
   5  Bilateral mutual adjustment    Rate of return
   6  Credit-based mudarabah         Capital, misreporting
   7   Musharakah & deferred sale    Capital, rate of return
   8  Third party hedging            Capital, rate of return
   9  Diversified deferred price     Capital, return, liquidity
   10 Parallel murabaha              Currency
   11 Value-based hybrid salam       Capital, return, liquidity


                                  VIII
                             CONCLUSION

Risk is a challenge, for Islamic as well as conventional finance. Despite

all ingenious techniques invented for risk management, global markets

are becoming increasingly volatile, and financial crises appear more

frequently and more severely. As we have seen, conventional risk

instruments raise concerns about systemic instability, in addition to

legal and moral issues. These instruments can be used for both

hedging and gambling, as Kenneth Arrow points out, and no

guarantee exists they are directed for productive uses. In reality,

however, statistics show clearly that they are used for speculation and

gambling-like activities much more than for hedging.

       Specialists agree that risk can be managed but not eliminated

from economic activities. “Nothing ventured, nothing gained” is the

first maxim in the business world. Economic progress cannot be

achieved without assuming risk. Entrepreneurial spirit is the driving

force of prosperity, and thus risk-taking is an essential moral value.

       The challenge therefore is to be able to distinguish these two

opposite ends, and find instruments that selectively serve valuable risk

management but discourage gambling and unproductive behavior. As

it has become clear, human mind, left to its own, falls short of solving


142 VIII. CONCLUSION

this dilemma. The Divine guidance, however, points to the right path

to the solution. Teachings of the Qur’�n and Prophet Muhammad,

peace be upon him, provide the necessary framework for finding the

answer to this age-old challenge. At the heart of this framework is the

integration of risk management and value-creation. This integration

improves economic efficiency while it opens the door for unlimited

creativity.

        The paper is an attempt to outline this framework together

with practical examples. Suggested instruments cover wide range of

risks, including capital risk, liquidity risk, rate of return risk, as well as

currency risk. Major Islamic modes of finance, i.e. mudarabah ,

musharakah , murabaha , and salam, are discussed, and how related risks

can be managed. The discussion shows how Shar�cah is abundant with

genuine solutions that integrate risk management with value-creation.

These examples and instruments however are by no means conclusive

or final, but hopefully point to directions for fruitful and rewarding

future research.


                                      REFERENCES

al-Jarhi, M. (2002) “Transactions in Conventional and Islamic Economies,” in H.

    Ahmed, ed., Theoretical Foundations of Islamic Economics, Islamic Research and
    Training Institute, Jeddah, Saudi Arabia.

Allais, M. (1993) The Monetary Conditions of an Economy of Markets, Islamic Research

    and Training Institute, Jeddah, Saudi Arabia.

al-Suwailem, S. (1999) “Towards an Objective Measure of Gharar in Exchange,”

    Islamic Economic Studies, vol. 7, pp. 61-102. Web address: www.islamic-
    finance.net.

al-Suwailem, S. (2002) “Decision-making Under Uncertainty: An Islamic

    Perspective,” in M. Iqbal and D. Llewellyn, eds., Islamic Banking and Finance,
    Edward Elgar.

al-Suwailem, S. (2005a) “Design of New Sukuk Products,” presented at the First

    International Islamic Financial Markets Conference, Bahrain, May 16-17.

al-Suwailem, S. (2005b) “Optimal Sharing Contracts: Properties and Evolution,” in

    M. Iqbal and T. Khan, eds., Financial Engineering and Islamic Contracts, Palgrave
    McMillan.

al-Yousef, Y. (2005) “Speculative Capital: An Islamic View,” presented at the 6th

    International Conference on Islamic Economics and Finance, Jakarta,
    Indonesia, November, 21-24.

Arrow, K. (1971) Essays in Risk Bearing, Markham Publishing Company.

Arrow, K. (2003), “Interview,” in Financial Engineering News, September/October

    issue. Web address: www.fenews.com/fen33.

Ashkenas, R., D. Ulrich, T. Jick, and S. Kerr, eds. (2002) The Boundaryless

    Organization, Jossey-Bass.

Atta-Mensah, J. (2004) “Commodity-Linked Bonds: A Potential Means for Less-

    Developed Countries to Raise Foreign Capital,” Bank of Canada Working
    Paper 2004-20, Ontario.

Banks, E. (2004) The Credit Risk of Complex Derivatives, 3rd ed., Palgrave McMillan.

Ben-Ner, A. and L. Putterman, eds. (1998) Economics, Values, and Organization,

    Cambridge University Press.

Bennett, P. (2004) “Why Are Capital Markets Catastrophic, and Are They

    Becoming More So?” in Handbook of World Stock, Derivative and Commodity
    Exchanges, Mondovision, U.K. Web address: www.exchange-handbook.co.uk.


144 REFERENCES

Bernstein, P. (1996) Against the Gods, John Wiley & Sons.

Bertismas, D., L. Kogan, and A. Lo (2001) “Hedging Derivative Securities and

    Incomplete Markets: An �-Arbitrage Approach,” Operations Research, vol. 49, pp.
    372-397.

Besley, T. and A. Powell (1989) “Commodity-Indexed Debt in International

    Lending,” World Bank PPR Working Papers Series 161, Washington, D.C.

Binmore, K. (1992) Fun and Games: A Text on Game Theory, D.C. Heath and Co.

Bodie, Z. and R. Merton (1998) Finance, Prentice Hall.

Borensztein, E., M. Chamon, O. Jeanne, P. Mauro, and J. Zettelmeyer (2004)

    Sovereign Debt Structure for Crisis Prevention, IMF Occasional Paper 237, Washington
    D.C.

Borna, S. and J. Lowry (1987) “Gambling and Speculation,” Journal of Business Ethics,

    vol. 6, pp. 219-224.

Buckman, R. (1997) What You Really Need to Know about Cancer, Johns Hopkins

    University Press.

Buffet, W. (2002) “Chairman’s Letter,” in Annual Report, Berkshire Hathaway Inc.

Chance, D. (1995) “A Chronology of Derivatives,” Derivatives Quarterly, vol. 2, pp. 53-

    60.

Chance, D. (2003) “Hedging,” in DerivaQuote,

    www.bus.lsu.edu/academics/finance/faculty.

Chapra, M.U. (2004) “The Case Against Interest,” presented at the International

    Conference on Islamic Banking and Finance, Brunei, Jan. 5-7.

Chorafas, D. (2003) Alternative Investments and the Mismanagement of Risk, Palgrave

    McMillan.

Covey, S. (1990) The Seven Habits of Highly Effective People, Simon and Suchster.

de Bono, E. (1970) Lateral Thinking: Creativity Step by Step, Harper & Row, Publishers.

DeGroot, M. (1986) Probability and Statistics, 2nd ed., Addison-Wesley.

Deutsche Bundesbank (2003) Monthly Report, January.

Dodd, R. (2005) “Providing Credit in Times of Crisis,” Financial Policy Forum,

    Derivatives Study Center, Washington, D.C. Web address:
    www.fiancialpolicy.org.

Drucker, P. (1999) “Innovate or Die,” The Economist, September 23.

Elster, J. (2000) Ulysses Unbound: Studies in Rationality, Precommitment, and Constraints,

    Cambridge University Press.

Evans, P. and T. Wurster (2000) Blown to Bits: How the New Economics of Information

    Transforms Strategy, Harvard Business School.


REFERENCES 145

Financial Economists Roundtable (1994) “Statement on Derivatives Market and

   Financial Risk,” FER, www.stanford.edu/~wfsharpe/art/fer/fer.htm.

Finnerty, J. (1988) “Financial Engineering in Corporate Finance: An Overview,”

   Financial Management, vol. 17, pp. 14-33.

Finnerty, J. (1994) “Financial Engineering,” in P. Newman, M. Milgate and J.

   Eatwell, eds., New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, McMillan Press, vol. 2,
   pp. 56-63.

Freeman, R. (1993) “Finding a Cure for Derivatives: The Market Cancer,” The New

   Federalist, September. Web address:
   members.tripod.com/~american_almanac/derives.htm.

Friedman, J. (1990) Game Theory with Applications to Economics, 2nd ed., Oxford

   University Press.

Gates, J. (1998) The Ownership Solution: Toward a Shared Capitalism for the 21 st Century,

   Addison-Wesley.

Gigerenzer, G., P. Tedd, and the ABC Research Group (1999) Simple Heuristics that

   Make Us Smart, Oxford University Press.

Gintis, H. (2000) Game Theory Evolving, Princeton University Press.

Gintis, H., S. Bowles, R. Boyd, and E. Fehr, eds. (2005) Moral Sentiments and Material

   Incentives: The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life, MIT Press.

Goldberg, D. (1989) Genetic Algorithms in Search, Optimization, and Machine Learning,

   Addison-Wesley.

Gowland, P. (1994) The Economics of Modern Banking, Edward Elgar.

Greenspan, A. (1999) “Financial Derivatives,” presented before the Futures Industry

   Association, Boca Raton, Florida, March 19. Web address:
   www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/1999.

Greenspan, A. (2002) “International Financial Risk Management,” presented before

   the Council on Foreign Relations, Washington, D.C., November 19. Web
   address: www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2002.

Greenspan, A. (2003) “Corporate Governance,” presented at the 2003 Conference

   on Bank Structure and Competition, Chicago, Illinois, May, 8. Web address:
   www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2003.

Group of Thirty (1993) Derivatives: Practices and Principles, Washington, D.C.

Group of Thirty (1997) Global Institutions, National Supervision and Systemic Risk,

   Washington, D.C.

Hansmann, H. (1996) The Ownership of Enterprise, Harvard University Press.

Heffernan, S. (1996) Modern Banking in Theory and Practice, John Wiley & Sons.


146 REFERENCES

Hieronymus, T. (1977) Economics of Futures Trading, Commodity Research Bureau,

    New York.

Holland, J. (1995) Hidden Order: How Adaptation Builds Complexity, Basic Books.

Iqbal, Z. (1999) “Financial Engineering in Islamic Finance,” Thunderbird International

    Business Review, vol. 41, pp. 541-559.

Islamic Financial Services Board (IFSB), (2005) “Guiding Principles of Risk

    Management,” Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia.

Jehle, G.A. (1991) Advanced Microeconomic Theory, Prentice Hall.

Kelley, K. (1994) Out of Control, Basic Books.

Keynes, J. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, Harcourt Brace

    Jovanovich, Publishers.

Khalil, A., C. Rickwood, and V. Murinde (2002) “Evidence on Agency-contractual

    Problems in Mudarabah Financing Operations by Islamic Banks,” in M. Iqbal
    and D. Llewellyn, eds., Islamic Banking and Finance, Edward Elgar.

Khan, M. and A. Mirakhor, eds. (1987) Theoretical Studies in Islamic Banking and Finance,

    Institute of Islamic Studies, Texas.

Khan, T. and H. Ahmed (2001) Risk Management: An Analysis of Issues in Islamic

    Financial Industry, Islamic Research and Training Institute, Jeddah, Saudi
    Arabia.

Köhler, H. (2004) “Building Shared Prosperity in the Americas,” presented at the

    Special Summit of the Americas, Monterrey, January, 12. Web address:
    www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2004/011204.htm.

Kreitner, R. (2000) “Speculation of Contract, or How Contract Law Stopped

    Worrying and Learned to Love Risk,” Columbia Law Review, vol. 100, May, pp.
    1096-1138.

Krugman, P. (1999) The Return to Depression Economics, W.W. Norton.

Leathers, C. and J.P. Raines (2004) “The Schumpeterian Role of Financial

    Innovations in the New Economy’s Business Cycle,” Cambridge Journal of
    Economics, vol. 28, pp. 667-681.

Lessard, D. (1986) “The Management of International Trade Risks,” The Geneva

    Papers in Risk and Insurance, vol. 11, pp. 255-264.

LiPuma, E. and B. Lee (2005) “Financial Derivatives and the Rise of Circulation,”

    Economy and Society, vol. 34, pp. 404-427.

Lowenstein, R. (2000) When Genius Failed: The Rise and Fall of Long Term Capital

    Management, Random House.

MacCrimmon, K. and D. Wehrung (1986) Taking Risks: The Management of Uncertainty,

    Free Press.


REFERENCES 147

Mandelbrot, B. and R. Hudson (2004) The (Mis)Behavior of Markets: A Fractal View of

    Risk, Ruin, and Return, Basic Books.

March, J. (1994) A Primer on Decision Making, Free Press.

Marshall, J. and V. Bansal (1992) Financial Engineering, New York Institute of Finance.

Mason, S., R. Merton, A. Perold, and P. Tufano (1995) Cases in Financial Engineering,

    Prentice Hall.

Merton, R. (1973) “An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model,” Econometrica, vol.

    41, pp. 867-887.

Merton, R. (1992) “Financial Innovation and Economic Performance,” Journal of

    Applied Corporate Finance, vol. 4, pp. 12-22.

Milgrom, P. and J. Roberts (1992) Economics, Organization & Management, Prentice

    Hall.

Miller, M. (1986) “Financial Innovations: The Last Twenty Years and the Next,”

    Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, vol. 21, pp. 459-471.

Mitchell, M. (1998) An Introduction to Genetic Algorithms, MIT Press.

Myers, S. (2001) “Capital Structure,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 15, pp. 81-

    102.

North, D. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Cambridge

    University Press.

Obaidullah, M. (2005) Islamic Financial Services, King Abdul-Aziz University, Jeddah,

    Saudi Arabia.

Office of Comptroller of the Currency (2005) OCC Bank Derivatives Report, Second

    Quarter.

Pais, A. (1982) Subtle is the Lord: The Science and the Life of Albert Einstein, Oxford

    University Press.

Partnoy, F. (1997) “Financial Derivatives and the Costs of Regulatory Arbitrage,”

    Journal of Corporation Law, vol. 22, pp. 211-227.

Partnoy, F. (2003) Infectious Greed: How Deceit and Risk Corrupted the Financial Markets,

    Henry Holt and Company.

Pilbeam, K. (2005) Finance and Financial Markets, 2nd ed., Palgrave McMillan.

Raines, J.P. and C. Leathers (1994) “Financial Derivative Instruments and Social

    Ethics,” Journal of Business Ethics, vol. 13, pp. 197-204.

Saber, N. (1999a) Speculative Capital, vol. 1, Pearson Education Ltd.

Saber, N. (1999b) Speculative Capital & Derivatives, vol. 2, Pearson Education Ltd.

Santos, J. (2004) “A History of Futures Trading in the United States,” in R.

    Whaples, ed., EH.Net Encyclopedia, www.eh.net.


148 REFERENCES

Schelling, T. (1980) The Strategy of Conflict, Harvard University Press.

Shapira, Z. (1995) Risk Taking: A Managerial Perspective, Russell Sage Foundation.

Shiller, R. (2000) Irrational Exuberance, Princeton University Press.

Shiller, R. (2003) The New Financial Order: Risk in the 21st Century, Princeton University

    Press.

Silber, W. (1983) “The Process of Financial Innovation,” American Economic Review,

    vol. 73, pp. 89-95.

Slutz, R. (2004) “Should We Fear Derivatives?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol.

    13, pp. 173-192.

Sobel, J. (2005) “Interdependent Preferences and Reciprocity,” Journal of Economic

    Literature, vol. 43, pp. 392-436.

Sornette, D. (2003) Why Stock Markets Crash: Critical Events in Complex Financial Systems,

    Princeton University Press.

Sparks, D. (2000) “Business Won’t Hedge the Euro Away,” BusinessWeek, at:

    businessweek.com/2000/00_49/b3710177.htm.

Spence, D., ed., (1997) Introduction to Futures and Options, Futures and Options

    Association, Woodhead Publishing Ltd.

Steinherr, A. (2000) Derivatives: The Wild Beast of Finance, John Wiley & Sons.

Stiglitz, J. (2001) “Information and the Change in the Paradigm of Economics,”

    Prize Lecture. Web address: nobelprize.org/economics.

Stiglitz, J. (2002) Globalization and its Discontents, W.W. Norton & Co.

Stiglitz, J. (2003) “Dealing with Debt: How to Reform Global Financial System,”

    Harvard International Review, pp. 54-59. Web address: hir.harvard.edu.

Sullivan, R. (2005) “Why Options?”, at www.optionsxpress.com.

Summa, J. (2003) “Do Option Sellers Have a Trading Edge?” Investopedia, at:

    www.investopedia.com.

Summers, L. and V. Summers (1989) “When Financial Markets Work Too Well: A

    Cautious Case for Securities Transaction Tax,” Journal of Financial Services
    Research, vol. 3, pp. 261-286.

Swan, E. (2000) Building Global Market: A 4000 Year History of Derivatives, Kluwer Law

    International.

Teweles, R. and F. Jones (1987) Futures Game: Who Wins, Who Loses, and Why, 2nd ed.,

    McGraw-Hill Book Company.

Tickell, A. (2000) “Dangerous Derivatives: Controlling and Creating Risks in

    International Money,” Geoforum, vol. 31, pp. 87-99.


REFERENCES 149

Tobin, J. (1978) “A Proposal for International Monetary Reform,” Eastern Economic

    Journal, vol. 3, pp. 153-159.

Tumpel-Gugerell, G. (2003) “The Volatility of Financial Markets,” presented at the

    Third International Financial Meeting in Madrid, July 1-2. Web address:
    www.ecb.int.

West’s Encyclopedia of American Law (1998), West Publishing Co., available from

    www.answers.com/topic/commercial-papers.

World Bank (2005) “Indicators of Finance,” series code [27]. Web address:

    unstats.un.org.

Wright, R. (2000) Nonzero: The Logic of Human Destiny, Pantheon Books.

Varian, H. (1992) Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd ed., W.W. Norton.

Arabic References

 .`ß1418 ,Øú�d¬ºæ CFïÚæ ,�«�ëédG ÜÓ£f »a �«dódG ÜÉ«f ,°ÆôRòæ ZB| •A ZüQ¿æ ,�ÆüÆE •Aæ [1]
                  .`ß1415 ,Zh^òæ �BFïú ,è�µ°TCG êÉjBG ô«°ùØL ,°ÆôRòæ ZB| •A ZüQ¿æ ,�ÆüÆE •Aæ [2]
        .`ß1422 ,�b¨Nòæ •Aæ ]æY ,á«¡�ØdG á«HGQƒÑdG óYGƒ�dG ,°ÆôRòæ ZB| •A ZüQ¿æ ,�ÆüÆE •Aæ [3]
       ,°døã •A ZüRú´ •üQ^òæ ZB| ~üM ,ihÉéØdG ´ƒªàe,°ÆôRòæ ZB| •A ZüQ¿æ ,�ÆüÆE •Aæ [4]
                                                                                 .��Y¨}eòæ �}Buòæ
                    .¢1989 ,`ß1409 ,^i§òæ´ �|øBuôò ^Nß ,»Ñ¨ªdG ,ZüQ¿æ •A ıæ ZB| ,�úæZã •Aæ [5]
   .`ß1423 ,�b¨Nòæ •Aæ ]æY ,Ö«ªdÉ©dG ¿Q ÖY Ö«©bƒªdG �ÓYEG ,^ïA ØA¿æ •A ZüRú ,°Æëòæ •Aæ [6]
        ,»eÓ°SE’G OÉ°üéb’G •üp ,'•Æú¿øFòæ Ù �Æú�d¬ºæ �}�^iòæ °ïQ' ,ZúøQ •ÆeQ ,¶øeQ [7]
                                   .¢1980 ,`ß1400 ,Øú�d¬ºæ YømFã�ò õ´¿ºæ ^üEªÚæ •ú ±]øFVú L¨RA
            ,��]Z§ïd¬ºæ ,�Æú�d¬ºæ �ÆòøÚæ �|ø§mòæ ±´Z£ ,'�ÆòøÚæ �dZ§®òæ �|ø§l' ,Øúød ,°ô�¨eòæ [8]
                                                                                      .¢2000 ,`ß1421
                                 .¢2003 ,`ß1423 CM] ,'•Æú¿øFòæ �Æqã Ù Høàã´' ,Øúød ,°ô�¨eòæ [9]
  ,�Æú�d¬ºæ �Æá^mÚæ ^tøVú ±´Z£ ,'^tøVÚæ ±]æY¬º ±^ïFBú Hæ´Y¿æ •| KRBòæ' ,Øúød ,°ô�¨eòæ [10]
                                                              .¢2004 ,`ß1424 ,sø�^òæ ,Ù^mÚæ Z®}Úæ


150 REFERENCES

                        .¢1997 ,`ß1417 ,¶øà| •Aæ ]æY ,êÉ�aGƒªdG ,ìøRd¬æ •A °Æßæ^A¬æ ,ØBtøiòæ [11]
           .¢1990 ,`ß1410 ,öÆNòæ ]æY ,Oƒ�©dG »a �ôKCGh Qô¨dG ,•Æú¿ºæ ZüRú í�Zmòæ ,^�^qòæ [12]
       .¢2002 ,`ß1423 ,ØRMæ^òæ ä^mú ,'°ÆôeFòæ ¢¨� ì¨eòæ ^}eA °ôeòæ' ,�Æ|^iòæ �|¨üNÚæ [13]
   .¢2006 ,Høú¨ô}Úæ �ƧëFò �ÆA^}òæ ,»eÓ°SE’G ¬�ØdG ™ªàe á�àe ,Øú�d¬ºæ ^üEªÚæ �üy§ú [14]


{þĿČĽ}¦Aä÷¥ =§AÅ Ŀ7 BÂEüĽ{¥ ĿýĽ› úBă¥AĆEãAÁ BÆC¿™Aą} ABOUT THE AUTHOR

Sami Ibrahim al-Suwailem obtained his Bachelor’s degree in Science

from King Saud University in Riyadh in 1987. He obtained his

Mater’s degree from Southern Illinois University in Carbondale in

1990, and in 1995 obtained his Ph.D. from Washington University in

St. Louis, Missouri, both in Economics. He joined Al Rajhi Bank in

1995 as a senior consultant, and in 1998 became Manager of

Research & Development in the Shari’ah Group at the Bank. He

joined IRTI in December 2004.

ABOUT THE BOOK

The last decade witnessed an increasing trend in markets’ volatilities

and financial crises. During the same period, derivatives, the most

common instruments for hedging, have been growing at an

exponential rate. Apparently, derivatives did not help to stabilize

markets and attenuate financial crises. This is not difficult to explain,

since derivatives are also the main instruments for speculation. More

than 97% of derivatives are used for speculation, while less than 3%

are used for hedging. The challenge therefore is to search for

instruments that allow for productive risk management without

harmful speculation. This is the theme of Islamic finance that the

paper explores. Based on Shari’ah rules of gharar, the paper therefore

suggests several instruments for managing and hedging risks

associated with Islamic modes of finance.

Topics

I. Introduction

II. State of Risk: Volatilities of Financial Markets

III. Derivatives

IV. The Islamic Approach

V. Theory of Gharar

VI. Financial Engineering: An Islamic Perspective

VII. Islamic Instruments for Hedging

VIII. Conclusion